Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


PART II. POLICIES TO PROMOTE SUSTAINABLE COMMERCIAL AQUACULTURE


Among the pre-requisites for successful commercial aquaculture discussed in the previous chapters, some are outside the control of governments and policy-makers, and are non-policy variables. Non-policy variables are cultural factors such as the prevalence of entrepreneurship and risk-taking, and demand characteristics such as the size of a market or competition from substitutes. Other conditions can be influenced by governments. They are policy variables. Some of the enabling policies which governments can implement to promote the sector are general in scope. They are designed to reduce risks and lower costs for all business activities by creating a climate conducive to all private investments, including investment in the aquaculture sector. Such policies that are "business-friendly" to all investments are referred to as non-sector specific policies. In addition, there are sector-specific policies that focus on the promotion of a particular sector such as commercial aquaculture. Both non-sector specific and sector specific policies are discussed in this section.

CHAPTER 5. NON-SECTOR SPECIFIC POLICIES

Enabling policies are designed to encourage confidence among investors. Non-sector specific economic enabling policies would include good governance, openness to trade and macroeconomic growth, and emphasis on private investment.

Good Governance

Policies that address issues of policy instability, uncertainty over property rights, corruption, and a weakening of institutional factors, such as bankruptcy laws and contract enforcement are subsumed under the term "governance" (Hong et al., 1999). In a survey of firms in Africa, foreign-owned companies ranked political and policy stability as the most important determinant of whether to invest in the Continent and among the principal causes of investment success or failure. Domestic firms also ranked political risk as a major consideration, although behind other factors such as taxes, and infrastructure. In most of the twenty sub-Saharan countries surveyed, businesses complained about political instability, the certainty of rules and laws, and the honouring of contracts by governments (World Economic Forum, 1998). Political and social stability were a determining factor in the success of commercial tilapia production in Costa Rica (Porras, 2000).

Property rights are important because they affect incentives for producers to internalise externalities. Decisions whether to invest and whether to pollute are affected by property rights. In the coastal region of Honduras, shrimp farming has been handicapped by competing land claims (Morales, 2000). In West Bengal, India, farmers cite the plurality of land ownership as the most important constraint to aquaculture (Bhatta, 1999). To ease the constraint, certain State governments have expanded use rights through longer lease periods. Similarly, in the Pacific Islands, private ownership may be incompatible with the custom of communal tenure of coastal marine areas (Adams et al., 2000). In Thailand, lack of clear tenure was a major constraint to investments in water systems, and improved water management. Overcrowding of shrimp farms had led to proposals for sea irrigation, but for the investment in water management to be profitable, a large area was needed (Tokrisna, 1999). Unclear property rights handicapped the project.

A variety of land rights exists in sub-Saharan Africa. In some cases, land rights are not clearly defined. This can be costly and wasteful as it increases the price of land for investors, and can cause land disputes. Also, in most cases, the land acquisition process is usually long and fraudulent (Platteau, 1992; Ezenwa, 1994). Some countries, such as the Côte d' Ivoire, have individual titles with no restrictions. Others, such as Kenya and Malawi, impose restrictions. In Mozambique, Nigeria and Zambia land is vested in the state; individuals only have rights to occupancy and usage. Foreign investors are concerned that land title will not be validated, and occupiers are reluctant to lease in case the rights are transferred to the new user. Freely tradable property offers mobility, incentives and collateral. However, the issue of land rights is very sensitive, and title to land ownership may be less important for commercial aquaculture than that of guaranteed use and occupancy with a lease for a fixed number of years. In Bangladesh, there has been increased pond leasing, and since 1994/95 China has permitted the transfer of land use for a longer period. In Madagascar, shrimp farming occurs in industrial free-trade zones (IFTZ), which are located in a public domain. Foreign investors can only lease IFTZ land. Nevertheless, the land is leased for a period long enough (20 to 50 years renewable) to stimulate investment (Hishamunda, 2000c; Razafitseheno, 2000). The land usufruct is transferable.

Private investment is also inversely related to corruption. Foreign direct investment, especially, reacts very negatively to corruption (Alesina and Weder, 1999). This is particularly so for more irreversible forms of foreign direct investment such as investment in farming. By pushing firms outside the formal regulatory process and obliging managers to spend time and money with government officials, corruption raises transaction costs. If the top officials are monopolist rent seekers, the private sector can be forced into a prisoner's dilemma where the dominant strategy is to bribe (Klitgaard, 1998). A corrupt equilibrium is reached but at high social cost (Mauro, 1996).

To some extent, corruption is negatively related to the macroeconomic conditions of a country. Where officials are not paid, or are paid at a rate lower than subsistence, bribery can be a means of survival. Higher economic growth should result in higher salaries and lower corruption. Corruption is also positively related to monopolistic and discretionary power (and inversely related to accountability). By reducing arbitrary regulatory authority, structural reform packages, are a means of combating corruption. The Directorate of Corruption and Economic Crime in Botswana has also shown that public education can be an effective weapon and deterrent against corruption (Transparency International, 1999; Fombad, 1999).

Institutional factors are determinants of private investment. On the one hand, they can encourage investors to have a long-term perspective. On the other hand, they may deter investors if they reduce competitiveness, are time-consuming and encourage corruption. In some sub-Saharan African countries, businesses report that regulations are imprecise and impose a heavy burden on competitiveness. In others, almost a quarter of the time of senior management is spent obtaining or negotiating licences and regulations (World Economic Forum, 1998). Strengthening of institutions can be done through establishment of regulations and their implementation.

Openness to Trade and Macroeconomic Growth Policies

Economic enabling policies would also include openness to trade and macroeconomic growth. Both are positive determinants of private investment. Research has demonstrated that economic growth can be accelerated by openness to trade, attraction of foreign investment, investment in health and education and domestic private sector investment (Sachs, 1998). These policies are as relevant to Africa as elsewhere. The flow of capital investment in sub-Saharan Africa is low. The ratio of total investment to GDP, which is approximately 17%, is below those of the developing countries of Asia (29%) and of the Western Hemisphere (22%). Moreover, private investment, which is more productive than public investment, remains small. The ratio of private to public investment in the region is significantly below that of Asia and Latin America. This relatively small access to private capital flows is one of the major constraints to the region's economic development (World Economic Forum, 1998). Internationally, Africa faces the risk of being marginalised. Africa's share of world trade has fallen from 4% in the early 1980's to 2% in 1996. The Continent attracts only 1.3% of world's total direct foreign exporting countries (Sachs, 1998). Countries that are non oil-exporters in sub-Saharan Africa have therefore a share of world foreign direct investment that approaches zero (0.3%).

Historically, macroeconomic conditions have not been favourable in sub-Saharan Africa. The region's economic growth was 1999). Of the world's 48 poorest Saharan Africa, real GDP was almost stagnant between 1992-94 with actual declines in real GDP per capita (Ouattara, 1999). Over those years, average inflation rates ranged from 44% to 61%. However, the years 1995-1999 have seen an improvement in the macro-economic performance of sub-Saharan Africa. Real growth rates averaged about 5% between 1995 and 1998; the inflation rate has fallen to 10% in 1998, and current account and fiscal deficits as a proportion of GDP have fallen. The indicators are even more positive if Nigeria and South Africa, which account for approximately half the region's GDP, are excluded (Ouattara, 1999).

Administrative reforms have been undertaken with liberalisation of the agricultural sector, increased openness to trade, and some curtailment of government intervention. Structural reforms including the dismantling of government monopolies, the establishment of market-determined interest rates and the privatisation of some government enterprises, have been implemented (Hernández-have not always welcomed the dismantling of state control to the benefit of the private sector. The pace of reform in sub-Saharan Africa has been determined as much by this political expediency as by economic rationality (Rotberg, 1998). However, political leadership in certain countries has demonstrated that reforms can be implemented with long-term improvements in economic growth and competitiveness (World Economic Forum, 1998).

Measures that maintain a constant real effective exchange rate and stability of the exchange rate are also important macroeconomic growth enabling policies. Inappropriate exchange rates adversely affect business confidence and viability. An overvalued exchange rate is an impediment to exports; it also encourages the import of tradable imports. In most sub-Saharan countries, output from commercial aquaculture competes against imported fish from the capture fisheries. Thus, an overvalued exchange rate reduces the competitiveness of aquaculture output by lowering the domestic price of fish imports. An example of the impact of an overvalued exchange rate was the surge of imports of an estuarine fish from Guyana, the "Banga Mary", into Jamaica in the mid-1990s. Because of high interest rates, the Jamaican currency appreciated. Overvaluation of the Jamaican dollar caused the price of the imported Banga Mary to fall to half that of domestically cultured tilapia. By 1997, Banga Mary had established itself as a cheap fish, displacing a quarter of the restaurant trade in tilapia. Unable to sell its product, the tilapia industry in Jamaica stagnated (Carberry, 2000). With the creeping devaluation of the currency later, tilapia recovered its market share.

In the Africa's CFA zone, not only exchange rate regime required a recessionary fiscal policy in order to maintain macroeconomic equilibrium. Thus, the reduction in the market for aquaculture outputs caused by competition from imports was compounded by declining real incomes. With positive income elasticity of demand for fish, lower incomes had a depressing impact on demand for output from commercial aquaculture. An enabling policy would avoid fluctuating and appreciating real effective exchange rates. A-300% devaluation of Costa 1981/1982 forced farms that had dollar credits to abandon their investment rather than incur the foreign exchange cost. The devaluation also forced the closure of a tilapia cage project because it was dependent on imported feed (Porras, 2000).

Emphasis on the Private Sector as the Source of Wealth Creation

Traditional development policies stressed market failures and the necessity for governments to intervene. Increasingly, however, this approach created inefficiencies and administrative gridlock. Incentives were ignored, and often results were contrary to the intentions. Throughout the 1980s and 1990s, approaches to economic development have evolved away from reliance on government towards greater emphasis on the private sector. The new development paradigm uses the neo-classical free market prescriptions to induce a more efficient allocation of resources. In the case of aquaculture development in sub-Saharan Africa, where public provision of inputs is jeopardised by fiscal retrenchment, the market model would be reflected in the privatisation of fingerling production and fish stations as well as in the production and distribution of feed by the private sector. Few countries can afford subsidies for feed, whatever the merits (Entsuah-Mensah et al., 1999).

A further factor behind greater reliance on the private sector has been pressure on government spending. For some countries in sub-Saharan Africa, the pressure to curtail government spending was imposed by the International Monetary Fund as part of structural adjustment packages. These packages focussed on budget and current account deficits. They produced adjustment shocks typically greater in Africa than in Asia (FAO, 1995). At the end of 1996, the total number of adjustment packages in sub-Saharan Africa had reached 163 (Diabré, 1998). For other countries, an overvalued fixed exchange rate with the French franc, which was only eased in 1994, forced governments to cut spending. The fixed exchange rate put pressure on government spending as the residual policy tool for maintaining macroeconomic and exchange rate stability.

CHAPTER 6. SECTOR-SPECIFIC POLICIES AT THE MACRO LEVEL

Sector-specific policies can be defined at the macro and micro levels. This chapter discusses those policies that are specific to aquaculture, and which are meant to guide the development of the sector as a whole. We refer to them as sector-specific policies at the macro level. At the macro level, policies can be regulatory/legal, administrative, and economic; the industry can also regulate itself. They are intended to provide an orderly development of the sector. Macro-level sector-specific policies can also be defined in response to existing or perceived issue on the supply or demand side of the industry. We refer to these policies as supply and demand-driven policies.

Regulatory/Legal, Administrative, Economic and Self-policing Frameworks

The aim of regulating aquaculture is to provide an orderly and sustainable environment for its development. Regulations reduce negative externalities such as pollution or conflicts over water rights, land rights, and seabed areas caused by open-access property regimes. Alternatively, regulations may aim for positive externalities as in the case of Norwegian licensing for salmon farming. The intent of imposing licences was to preclude industry concentration and enable entrepreneurs in the capture fisheries or agriculture to participate in small-scale farming. Licences were also allocated on a regional basis. This was to foster coastal development in northern regions.

Command and control regulations predominate in curbing environmental effects of aquaculture. In its use of public land and waterways, aquaculture can be a threat to the other users. In the Northwest of Spain, salmon (Salmo salar) and turbot (Scophthalmus sp.) cage culture compete with mussel (Mytilus edulis) rafts. In eastern Canada, salmon farms and herring (Clupea harengus) weirs compete for sites. The legal system may resolve such conflicts, but a more common approach is government intervention through zoning and permits (Millar and Aiken, 1995). One technique is to prioritise the use of water. Off Northwest Spain where shallow seas preclude extensive flushing, zoning has assigned salmon cages to more distant locations. In Chile, separate sea areas are zoned for salmon farming and the capture fisheries. In Zambia, protected areas exist because of concerns for water conservation, in Ecuador for defence reasons. In other countries, such as Malawi, a distinction is made between private and public water. The purpose is to ensure that aquaculture development will be sustainable economically, socially and environmentally.

A common feature of aquaculture regulation is the obligation to acquire permits to establish a farm. Permits are a means of regulating the industry through use rights, and of minimising negative interactions where there are conflicting land or water uses. Another use of permits is data gathering. An obligation attached to approval of permits could be the provision of statistics on production and on technical matters. In the Philippines, certain producers must supply quarterly reports on production (Bonucci et al., 1993). However, costs of monitoring and enforcement may be prohibitive. In Costa Rica, to help plan the sector, farms must register with INCOPESCA. Farms are expected to provide details on sales, inputs used, dates of harvest and production systems in a Register (Porras, 2000). However, the Register has not been implemented. There is no neither penalty on those who fail to register. Nor is there enough personnel to encourage compliance. Similarly in Thailand, registration of shrimp farms has not been fully implemented. Part of the problem has been unclear land title, but also concern over taxation (Tokrisna, 1999). To make farmers comply, a strategy would be to tie the renewal of permits to provision of information.

Procedures to obtain permits differ. To grant aquaculture permits, most countries have in common the obligation to furnish documentation on administrative and economic aspects, geographical location and technical data such as the species to be cultivated. In Chile, Mexico, Mozambique, the Philippines and Venezuela, environmental impact assessments are required before a permit is granted. This requirement may be limited to farms above a certain size, which could ignore the cumulative environmental impacts of many small farms. There may be a reluctance to require impact assessments because of their cost, and concern that the cost may deter investment or undermine the industry's competitiveness. In Chile, a five-year business development plan is also required with the application. Other countries require information on nationality, with Mexico and the Philippines restricting permits to citizens and France to members of the European Union (Bonucci et al., 1993). France also requires evidence of expertise in aquaculture. For unitary states, the application is addressed to the ministry of fisheries or an alternative, but who that is may depend on whether the application is for fresh water or marine sites. Most countries have a common permit for all species but some (France, New Zealand and the Philippines) require different permits for different species or for certain aquaculture techniques.

Obtaining the necessary permits may involve a number of different departments, be time-consuming and ultimately be discouraging to prospective investors. This suggests that regulations should not be overly burdensome. Regulatory measures frequently cover access to public land, the right to use water, the discharge of wastewater and even the quality of water. In some cases as in the Congo (Brazzaville), permission to establish an aquaculture grants, at the same time, the right to use public land and water. In other countries, distinct permits are required. As a minimum, regulations should cover a few key legal issues such as the general place of aquaculture in the legal system, access to land and water, environmental regulations, import of live fish and the introduction of non-indigenous species (Andreasson, 1997).

The duration of permits varies, but most are valid for several years. Permits that are for short periods, such as only one year as is the case in Singapore, may be too brief to provide sufficient incentive for investment in the sector (DeVoe, 1991). In Western Australia, aquaculture leases can extend up to twenty-one years, but licences are necessary and are only for twelve months. The short licence period enables regulators to control the site while the longer lease period provides time for farmers to amortise their investment.

In some countries, permits are tradable, which encourages efficiency and consolidation. The more efficient farms can acquire permits while the less successful farmers sell their licences and find alternative occupations. Nevertheless, protection of the public interest may require that transfers be approved as in New Zealand and Madagascar. This enables the government to prevent over-concentration of the industry. It also facilitates terminating the lease if regulations are not being implemented. In Chile, licences are given for an indefinite period and are tradable. However, the profitability of salmon farming encouraged speculative trading of licences and the government was forced to impose a moratorium on the issuance of new permits (Bjorndal and Aarland, 1999).

Regulation can produce inefficiency and bureaucratic rigidity, which impedes development and expansion, and can be difficult to enforce. Inefficiency and bureaucratic rigidity may be due to overlapping laws, regulations and jurisdictions. Overlapping jurisdictions complicate applications and have a dissuasive effect on the development of aquaculture. The danger is high in federal states. In Canada, to clarify responsibilities, the federal government has jurisdiction over the ocean environment while provincial governments have responsibility for the fresh water environment. Even so, one of Canada's priorities is rationalising aquaculture legislation to reduce the regulatory burden on the industry (Canadian International Development Agency, 2000). When the Fisheries Act was drafted, there was no aquaculture industry. Currently, there are 17 federal departments and agencies (in addition to provincial departments) with responsibilities for the sector (INFOFISH, 1999). Regulatory duplication is inevitable. Hence, a comprehensive review of aquaculture legislation is planned. In some other federal states such as Germany, India, Nigeria and the United States, responsibility for aquaculture is at the local level, but regulations over the environment or the transport of fish across boundaries are within federal jurisdiction. In Malaysia, marine aquaculture is primarily regulated by the federal government whereas riparian aquaculture (including shrimp culture) is primarily the responsibility of the States (Van-Houtte-Sabbatucci, 1999).

Where there are numerous regulations, applicants can be assisted by one-stop administrative procedures where all information is easily accessible. In India, the Aquaculture Authority, which was established as a result of a 1996 Supreme Court ruling and has the responsibility for coastal aquaculture, has extensively published its rules of procedures and shrimp farm application forms in newspapers and local languages (Sakthivel, 1998). It has also published guidelines on desirable shrimp density, feed and pond design. The aim (not always successful) is to expedite investment proposals. In Jamaica, several government agencies regulate aquaculture but to expedite applications, one agency (the Jamaica Promotions Limited), developed a brochure explaining exactly what was needed. The brochure, with its procedural information, eased the regulatory approval process, particularly for foreign investors (Wint, 1991). In the absence of a single document integrating regulatory material, an alternative is to have staff from different agencies at one site. In the Philippines, potential aquaculture investors can obtain details of all regulations at one office. In Canada, similar "one-stop shops" have been established to assist investors navigate overlapping federal and provincial jurisdictions in aquaculture. The "guichet unique" plays a similar role in Madagascar.

In some countries approval can take years because each permit is completely reassessed by each department (Filho, 1997). Slow regulatory approval has impeded the growth of the Chilean salmon farming industry. In 1997, only 15% of licensing applications submitted in 1995 had been processed (Bjorndal and Aarland, 1999). In Puerto Rico, aquaculture is a priority sector and farms are given tax holidays and loans. Yet, a new aquaculture enterprise needs, on the average, 2 to 3 years to acquire twenty permits (Wint, 1991). This suggests that once the proposals have been submitted, the approval process should be as quick and transparent as possible. This reduces the potential for corruption and increases the likelihood of investment. Deadlines should be imposed and each agency screen only within its area of competence. In addition, because monitoring and enforcement are time-consuming and expensive, the regulatory framework should be kept to a minimum. In fact, weak enforcement, rather than the absence of legislation, may be a contributing, if not the primary, factor of unsustainable practices in aquaculture (FAO, 1999c). Resources for monitoring may be lacking or there may be overlapping jurisdictions among departments. Thus, simple classifications may be optimal in countries where resources and personnel are limited (Neiland et al., 1999). Ideally, regulations should be cheap to monitor and enforce, and application procedures rapid.

There are many instances in sub-Saharan Africa where aquaculture comes under more than one department. This has led to duplication, rivalry and wastage (Coche et al., 1994). For example, in Zimbabwe, aquaculture extension comes under agriculture, but aquaculture development is under tourism. A preferable situation is to have one government agency responsible for the development of aquaculture. The agency would keep informed about other government departments that are related to food production and natural resources, and would co-ordinate the sector. In Costa Rica, INCOPESCA has been responsible for the development, regulation and research of aquaculture since 1994. In Honduras, DIGEPESCA not only regulates the sector but also prepares the aquaculture plan.

Compounding the problem of overlapping administrative jurisdictions is the frequent lack of a legislative framework specific to aquaculture. This is because aquaculture is in its infancy in many countries and plays only a minor role in the legislative framework for aquaculture exists in the majority of developed countries, some countries in Eastern Europe and in some countries in Asia such as the Philippines. Many countries in Africa have little or no aquaculture legislation. In the early 1990s, of twelve sub-Saharan countries surveyed, only three (Kenya, Madagascar, and Nigeria) had specific legislation, another three (Malawi, Tanzania, and Zimbabwe) had limited legislation, and some (Cameroon, Central African Republic, Congo, Côte d'Ivoire, and Zambia) had no specific aquaculture legislation (Coche et al., 1994). Instead, there is an enabling power to regulate the industry, and laws and regulations that have been drafted without aquaculture in mind are applied. Often, the power enables an individual, such as the Director of Fisheries, to regulate aquaculture. In Zambia, regulatory power is given to the Minister of Agriculture, Food and Fisheries under the 1974 Act (Mudenda, 2000). In Malawi, aquaculture is regulated under the 1973 fisheries legislation (Bonucci et al., 1993; Kapeleta, 2000).

The absence of specific legislation also results in aquaculture being administered usually under regulations of the capture fisheries (Andreasson, 1997). In fact, a more appropriate legislative framework for aquaculture, at least for land-based fish farming, might be agricultural. Like agriculture, aquaculture is concerned with food production with the main difference being the chief growing medium: water rather than soil. Issues such as access to land and water and treatment of effluents are similar. Therefore, an agricultural framework would appear appropriate, particularly for pond aquaculture. However, such a framework might not be suitable for coastal, inland waterways and marine aquaculture because of open-access property issues. Moreover, brackish water aquaculture such as shrimp farming may cause irreversible damage and justify particular regulations safeguarding coastal regions. In certain cases such as France and Spain, mariculture and fresh water aquaculture come under different legislation and in others such as Ecuador, only certain areas (coastal areas for shrimp) are regulated.

The absence of a legal status for aquaculture, which legally recognises that land and/or water can be used for aquaculture, may handicap development of the sector. In a survey of nine Near-East countries, weak legislation, particularly for environmental protection and the movement of aquatic animals, was cited more than any other problem as a constraint to the development of aquaculture (El Gamal, 2000). The lack of legislation was exacerbated by administrative impediments such as heavy bureaucracy and lack of co-operation between agencies controlling aquaculture. On the other hand, benefits from a legislative framework that is too complex may not be worth the cost. In 1984, consultants wrote an extensive 25-page document of legislative proposals for the Bahamas. However, as of the early 1990s, none of the proposals was enacted, because the size of the aquaculture industry was too marginal (Thompson, 1991).

Complementary measures to command and control techniques, are economic incentives, and self-policing by the industry itself. Economic incentives rely on prices as a signalling device to guide appropriate behaviour (Willman, 1999). They obviate some of the expense of monitoring and enforcement. As a positive incentive, Ecuador offers tax exemptions if waste water is treated; other countries levy a tax on waste water (FAO, 1999c). Other incentives include performance bonds, or deposits that are required and refunded if the environment remains undamaged. Taxes to discourage over-use of environmentally unfriendly substances, such as antibiotics, can be effective if demand for the aquaculture product is price elastic. Subsidies can also be used although they have the disadvantage of incurring a cost to governments (or donors). Loans at subsidised interest rates are offered in Sri Lanka for installing water treatment systems.

Self-policing through peer pressure can also be effective, particularly for those farmers with a long time-horizon. Best Management Practices are self-regulating management codes that may derive from government or could devolve from a producers' organisation (FAO, 1999c). In Yokohama, enforcement is community-based (Hideyuki, 1999). Fish farmers have an incentive to produce responsibly, and are more likely to internalise environmental externalities than many other activities because environmental damage directly affects their own output. From enlightened self-interest, farmers themselves have an incentive to reduce pollution. The use of antibiotics in Norwegian salmon farming has fallen dramatically since 1987 and is now almost negligible. Its use was a negative environmental externality but also a threat to the image of (and markets for) Norwegian farmed salmon (Bjorndal et al., 2000).

Another example of a result of self-policing is the decline in environmental damage from feed waste. Feed accounts for approximately 50% of total costs in Norwegian salmon farming. The burden of high feed costs, and the lower yields caused by pollution from excess waste encouraged lower feeding rates (Asche et al., 1999). In turn, lower feeding rates reduced feed wastage and ensuing environmental damage.

Supply and Demand-driven Sector-specific Policies

Divestiture from Fish Stations

One of the characteristics of aquaculture in sub-Saharan Africa is the existence of government -owned fish stations, many of which are derelict. Fish stations serve a number of purposes. In the first place, they produce fingerlings, which may be distributed free or subsidised to farmers. In the second place, they are a source of food fish. A third purpose is to provide a demonstration of aquaculture technology and practices to farmers. This is important in those areas where water management and husbandry practices are recent innovations. Other purposes of the stations are training and research.

Built by donors to diffuse knowledge of aquaculture to farmers, the operating costs could not be met by governments when donor funds were exhausted. They were then abandoned. In some cases, lack of money has forced managers to be entrepreneurial selling fish in the market. However, this revenue-generating practice may provoke opposition from senior administrators. Managers have been obliged to remit revenues from fish sales to the department, thereby undermining incentives. Moreover, the practice of selling fish from publicly funded stations does not provide a "level playing field" for commercial farmers who face unfair competition. Because of the precarious condition of some stations, an appropriate strategy is the divestiture of many fish stations to the private sector. In fact, there are recommendations that the number of government stations should be reduced by at least half within five years from 1999 (Moehl et al., 2000). While certain of the roles of these stations discussed above could and should devolve to the private sector, others, such as basic research and training, belong in the public domain. Because of the uncertain outcome of research and the impossibility to internalise all benefits, development research is not attractive to the private sector, at least at the early stages of the industry development. Also, maintaining the quality of broodstock requires government stations if private fingerling production is more interested in productivity than quality (Little, 1998). In Costa Rica, government stations undertook much of the development research on tilapia that the private company Aquacorporacion was able to apply. The experience of Costa Rica suggests that some government stations remain to undertake development research.

The advantage of privatising where possible is that privatisation relieves governments of operating costs. Privatisation also tends to boost efficient management. This has been the experience when parastatal operations in agriculture have been privatised (Cleaver, 1993). If there is no interest from investors, management at least could be privatised. With the efficient management, the station could become profitable thereby sparking interest from local investors.

There are also disadvantages of privatisation. Privatisation will, at least initially, lead to higher prices of fingerlings. This is almost inevitable in the initial stage. Over time, however, these higher prices should prompt interest from entrepreneurs, increased supply and an easing of prices. This has been the experience in Madagascar where all fingerling production has been privatised. Privatisation is also likely to lead to job losses because the private sector hires only if labour productivity matches wage rates. However, those workers remaining will receive higher wages, which at least partially compensates for the loss of jobs.

The procedure for divestiture could follow that of parastatal institutions in agriculture, many of which have been returned to the private sector in restructuring programmes (Cleaver, 1993). The first step is to settle liabilities and also often restructure management. The aim is to eliminate debt and offer the prospect of profitability before sale or lease. If there are to be job losses, workers should be fired by governments before the sale or lease. This removes the stigma from the new private company. As for the actual sale, there are a number of possibilities. One approach is for the government to set a price. If there is to be a price set, transparency is important; private investment bankers are often better equipped than governments to evaluate assets and organise privatisation. Another option is a sale by auction. Both procedures pose risks to small-scale farmers. An alternative is to give first right of refusal to local small-scale farmers and to encourage them to acquire stations through producer co-operatives. This approach was followed in Madagascar. Another alternative is to proceed first with a joint private-public venture with governments selling their shares over time. This requires less initial equity from investors and may be a suitable approach if the intention is to encourage local ownership. It also allows time for management learning and reduces risks. There must however be a commitment for full divestiture eventually.

Privatisation of Extension Services and Training

Viable commercial aquaculture does not obviate the need for extension services, but may alter the source of funding. Some of the funding could come from the private sector. In Costa Rica, the extension services have undertaken research on sites and species. The resulting know-how was passed to Aquacorporación. Jamaica, the publicly funded extension services were instrumental in establishing the tilapia industry through the provision of services such as site evaluation, advice on harvesting schedules and supply of seed stock (Carberry, 2000). Once the industry was successfully established, the University of the West Indies increasingly provided technical training activities. In addition, the largest commercial farm, Aquaculture Jamaica Ltd, gives small-scale sharecroppers technical advice, and provides private funding complementing publicly funded extension services. In the Philippines and Thailand, feed companies provide technical advice to farmers. In Samut Sakhon,Thailand, a Taiwanese (Province of China) company established a feed plant and then introduced shrimp culture. By providing information on culture techniques and pond management to farmers, the number of shrimp farms sharply increased in the 1980s with concomitant demand for feed (Tokrisna, 1999).

An alternative is a "fee-for-service" charge by which farmers pay for extension services according to usage. User-fees have the advantage of rationing scarce personnel and funds. User-pays policy also gives an incentive for up-grading technical advice. In addition, the private sector can assist with extension services, especially by encouraging better training of personnel and farmers. In the Philippines, feed companies train tilapia farmers. Clearly, this is not devoid of self-interest, but it can also serve the public gain. The user-pays method has equity and distributional implications, but it off-loads costs from the public sector, leaving publicly funded extension services able to concentrate on the non-commercial sector. This may be particularly appropriate in sub-Saharan Africa where there is concern that aquaculture technical competence will be diluted as budgetary pressures oblige aquaculture extension services to merge with the more important agricultural sector into a unified service (Entsua et al., 2000).

Promotion of Large Farms

In order to develop, commercial aquaculture requires infrastructure and inputs that may not be readily available. Madagascar's culture requires hatcheries, nurseries, processing plants, and either feed manufacturing, or facilities for stocking imported feed. To meet these constraints, Madagascar's strategy was to encourage investment from large-scale industrial operations (Kasprzyk et al., 1993). Only large operations had access to their own sources of capital and expertise, and could undertake the infrastructure investment profitably.

Large farms can also accelerate movement down the learning curve and, by their example, encourage others to enter the industry. Even though tilapia had been introduced into Honduras in 1932, output was still less than 200 tons until 1990. With the establishment of three large domestic farms in 1991, the industry developed; output increased to exceed 1500 tons in1995 (Morales, 2000). In the Pacific islands, the culture of pearl oysters appears to have benefited from the existence of large producers. Small-scale coastal cultivators have faced market obstacles. By their volume and their regularity in producing quality pearls, large producers opened the market and developed the industry. To obtain the advantages of market access provided by large firms in French Polynesia, the many small-scale producers of marine pearls provided spat to the large firms (Tisdell, 1998).

Another example of the importance of large farm sizes in the development of the industry is commercial tilapia production in Jamaica. Initially, aquaculture development strategies focused on rural aquaculture, which is small-scale. The development was slow because farmers wanted to produce for profit (Wint, 1996). The government then focussed on large-scale farms. In the early 1980s, two large farms were established. Tollgate was a joint venture between the National Investment Bank of Jamaica and an Israeli group, and Aquaculture Jamaica Ltd (AJL) a subsidiary of the Jamaica Broilers Group. The principal motivation of the Jamaica Broilers Group diversifying was to earn foreign exchange by exporting tilapia (Carberry, 2000). The Broilers Group later acquired Tollgate. Currently, its output accounts for approximately 90% of the annual national production of 3 600 tons. Because of its large size, the company was able to manage shocks. In 1998, when feed prices rose sharply, AJL was able to defer the impact through forward purchase arrangements (Carberry, 2000). It was also able to develop a marketing network through its export company, Jabexco, and exports almost half its output to the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom, Germany and Belgium. Its dominance of the industry has not had deleterious effects on the sector; indeed, the impact appears to have been positive. The farm has established a reputation for quality in its five export countries, with positive repercussions for the reputation of other Jamaican products (Wint, 1996). It has also encouraged others to produce tilapia. In order to increase exports, it has contracted some tilapia production to small and medium-scale farms in a scheme similar to its poultry operation. Currently, there are 11 such farms producing 850 tons annually (Carberry, 2000). Farmers receive a price lower than the retail price, but they are guaranteed inputs and a market. AJL also provides extension services to its contract farmers, sharing its husbandry practices and technological knowledge. Moreover, by its success, the company has stimulated interest by other large-scale firms in commercial aquaculture.

Promotion of Foreign Investment

If there is no or limited domestic involvement in commercial aquaculture, as is the case in sub-Saharan Africa, one strategy is to entice direct foreign investment. It expedites the acquisition of technology and expertise and can be the impetus for the whole sector. Joint ventures could be encouraged; they bring in foreign capital and expertise while offering domestic investors the opportunity to participate and gain technological knowledge.

However, foreign investors will require guarantees of profit and capital repatriation, and unrestricted currency conversion. Repatriation of profits is of singular concern to foreign investors (World Economic Forum, 1998). They may also expect tax exemptions and other incentives. Such incentives could be debt-equity swaps and tax holidays. Investors in aquaculture within the European Union can obtain reimbursement from the Union and their national governments of up to 40% of fixed capital costs. In addition, there may be interest rate subsidies. Unless returns in Africa are high enough to compensate for the risks of investing in the region, and for the additional equity invested, incentives may be necessary.

Incentives have economic cost. In addition, there may be the social cost of resentment against foreign domination of the sector. Some resentment by local people in the Tenth Region in Chile was created by foreign investment in salmon farming, although mitigated by upward pressure on all wages due to competition by aquaculture for the relatively scarce labour (Ridler, 1994). Also foreign investors may employ expatriate managers, leaving local workers to do unskilled labour jobs. There is also the likelihood that research and development will be undertaken at the head offices and not in the recipient country. These costs must be weighed against the benefits of acquiring technology, generating foreign exchange and developing a growth industry.

Chile has demonstrated that commercial aquaculture can develop by encouraging foreign investors. In the early 1990s, the ownership of Chilean salmon farms was primarily domestic, but the largest companies were predominantly foreign owned. In addition to Marine Harvest (Unilever), there were Salmones Antartica (Japanese) and Mainstream (British). Norway, the United States, Holland and New Zealand were also involved in the industry. Foreign investors were permitted to repatriate profits at any time, and all capital after three years (Chocair, 1991). There was a debt-equity agreement, which was designed to encourage foreign involvement in salmon farming by giving foreign investors a premium in Chilean pesos for foreign debt. By buying Chilean debt denominated in foreign currency in the secondary market, foreign investors were reimbursed the debt at face value in pesos. Not only did this policy reduce Chilean external debt denominated in hard currency, but it also prompted the industry development. The industry became a good source of foreign exchange with more than 90% of Chilean salmon production being exported[9]. By enticing large international firms to invest in the industry, Chile obviated the need to finance domestic producers through incentives and subsidies. The risks inherent in establishing a new industry and the costs of acquiring technology and knowledge were borne by the private sector.

Costa Rica also has developed its commercial aquaculture through encouraging foreign investment. As in Chile, most of its output is exported. One foreign firm from Europe, Aquacorporacion Internacional, dominates its tilapia industry. The foreign company's demand for feed was sufficiently large to stimulate feed production by domestic manufacturers. The company also prompted interest in the industry from domestic farmers, encouraging emulation and domestic investment in the sector (Porras, 2000).

In Honduras, tilapia farming was introduced in 1936 when a tilapia brood stock was imported from El Salvador. The focus was domestic small-scale farms. However, the industry failed to develop until 1990 when the interest shifted to commercial farming following government policies to encourage foreign investment in the sector. Also, the development of the shrimp farming industry was prompted by enabling government policies on foreign direct investment. In 1999, aquaculture was the country's fourth export earner after bananas, coffee and palm oil. On the average, it brings about 90 million US dollars gross per year into the national economy (Morales, 2000). In 1997, shrimp exports alone earned US$164 million (Hishamunda, 2000a).

In Africa, Madagascar's shrimp place policies that attract foreign investment. Of the three shrimp farms in Mozambique, one is privately owned by a national of Mozambique; the two largest belong to foreign (French) investors. Foreign investment appears to assist commercial aquaculture to take off and as a contributor to employment generation, transfer of technologies and diversification of exports. The Nigerian fish farming industry, which is one of the major fish producers in sub-Saharan Africa, developed because of foreign investment.

Introduction of Alien Species Policies

Among the most important questions for a farmer or a government policy-maker interested in promoting aquaculture is what species should be cultivated (Sandifer, 1991). As discussed previously, three factors should guide the choice of species for commercial aquaculture. The first factor is the market. Can the product be sold; what is its competitive advantage and will the market change. The second factor is technological. Can one produce the species? The third factor is the choice between an endemic and an introduced species. The latter choice arises if, to be economically viable, commercial aquaculture needs to introduce a non-indigenous species. Then, a balance must be struck between the ecological dangers from the import of alien species and potential benefits. This follows the approach of agriculture where much of modern output comes from introduced crops.

In its Database on Introductions of Aquatic Species, FAO has information on 3 150 introductions of 654 aquatic species. Evidence suggests that, while adverse effects from the introduction of new species for aquaculture are the exception, they have occurred, particularly with inland species (Bartley and Casal, 1999). The introduced species may become a pest, damaging the environment and even the farming of other species. The introduction of diseased shrimp into Taiwan (Province of China) adversely affected the marine shrimp industry. The introduction of Pacific oyster to Australia damaged farming of Sydney rock oyster by displacing the latter (Tisdell, 1998). Escapees also change the ecosystem. To protect against disease, most countries have regulations covering the importation of live fish and the introduction of exotic species. Zambia requires authorisation for the importation of live fish and Malawi has a prohibition on movement of live fish, which impinges on aquaculture (Bonucci et al., 1993).

Yet, in many countries, successful commercial aquaculture has occurred through the importation of a marketable species. This was the case of Costa Rica, Jamaica, Zambia and Zimbabwe with the O. niloticus. In these countries existing species were unpopular with consumers, but the introduction of O. niloticus and adroit marketing gave the industry impetus. In fact, the choice of tilapia as the target species in Jamaica was a critical factor in determining the industry's success (Carberry, 2000). Salmonids are not indigenous to Chile. However, the country's salmonid 1992, Chile became the world's second largest producer of farmed salmon with an output of more than 50 000 tons, from less then 3000 tons five years earlier. Because farming Atlantic salmon (Salmo salar) was more attractive than Pacific salmon due to lower mortality rates, higher cage density, and market opportunities in the United States, Chile switched away from Pacific to Atlantic salmon. By 1992, Chile was cultivating more Atlantic than Pacific salmon. In spite of its liberal access to imported salmon eggs, Chile has been fortunate so far in avoiding negative effects. The benefits in terms of jobs, income and foreign exchange have been considerable.

This information suggests that policy makers must weigh costs and benefits in their decision whether to introduce a new species for aquaculture, giving due attention to a thorough and proper a priori risk assessment according to recommended rules. Economic benefits of introducing a new species may outweigh ecological risks with net benefits in favour of introducing an alien species. However, risk management would suggest that the emphasis should be on prudence, alien species being introduced only as a last resort. FAO has established guidelines for the introduction of alien species.

Marketing Policies

In addition to providing incentives for foreign direct investment, governments can "kick-start" commercial aquaculture through marketing. Governments may opt to establish a market for the hygienic handling and selling of fish. The Fish Marketing Organisation in central Bangkok is a state enterprise for the selling of fish. Fish are sold through fish agents who must be registered with the Department of Fisheries. As the industry has developed, the role of marketing has increasingly passed to private assembly markets (Piumsombun, 1999). In China, the government has played an active role in investing in trading markets. There are more than 300 located in both consuming and producing areas (Huang, 1999). However, as in Thailand, the private sector is displacing the public sector in the marketing channel. In Jamaica, the government appointed a marketing officer. The objective was to create a market for the farmed fish. Taste tests were tried at government functions, recipe booklets were produced and cooking demonstrations were held on radio and television (Wint,1996). To help with logistics, the Inland Fisheries Unit provided transport for the big buyers, and also ice. These facilitating activities declined as the industry developed, with marketing and transport increasingly falling on the private sector as larger firms entered commercial aquaculture.

Promotion of Producer Associations

In most countries, aquaculture does not have the economic weight of agriculture or even the capture fisheries. Thus, its interests are often overlooked. Producer organisations can be useful just as a lobby group. Also, they are frequently used as a means of exchanging information and diffusing technical knowledge. For tradable species, a major role of producers associations is to increase market share by product differentiation. Brand marketing to differentiate products, perhaps according to the pristine growing environment, is an attempt to move away from commodity pricing towards monopolistic competition and price setting. In addition, producer associations can collaborate to increase the demand through generic marketing. Through their associations, rival salmon producers from Canada, Chile and the USA have completed a three-year marketing campaign to promote farmed salmon in the USA, their major market. Approximately 30 million consumers were reached in a number of target cities. The evidence indicates that the campaign has been successful with young consumers of an income of more than $50 000 a year (Infante, 1999). Consumption of farmed salmon in the targeted cities grew by an average of 9% more than in control cities where there was no generic campaign. There are projections that the US market for farmed Atlantic salmon will more than double between 2000 and 2005 (Kontali Analyse, 1999).

In its most effective form, a producer organisation markets the product ensuring that the quality is consistently high, self-polices regulations and even funds applied research. Examples of associations that provide a gamut of services are the Chilean Salmon and Trout Growers' Association, the Fundación Chile and Costa Rica’s TILACOOP. In Chile, marketing was one of the main tools for promoting the industry, but through producer associations. In 1986 when output was 1,000 tons and exports were only worth 5 million dollars, the Association of Chilean Salmon and Trout farmers was established. Producers contributed $0.03 per kilo. In return, the Association maintained HACC (hazard analysis and critical control points) quality standards and advertised. The quality standards aimed at ensuring that all products exported were of a uniformly high quality, and thereby reassuring buyers. By 1989, the Association was spending 2.8% of sales revenues on marketing; more (as a percentage) than Norway and Scotland combined. In 1998, output had grown to more than 200 000 tons and exports were worth 714 million dollars (Shaw and Gabbott, 1999).

As the industry matured, the Chilean Association that has been active in brand and generic marketing and maintaining quality standards has encouraged self-regulation of the industry in order to minimise government interventions. Self-regulation is done through successful enforcement of its equivalent of a Code of Conduct for best aquaculture management practices. It has also funded research on environment issues and diseases that are of direct concern to the industry, and encouraged the transfer of technology through its Salmon Technology Institute, which was founded in 1993.

Fundación Chile was instrumental in promoting salmon farming by establishing farms that were later sold, and has actively encouraged technology transfer. Its present research is on disease and nutrition (Bjorndal and Aarkland, 1999). In Costa Rica, small-scale tilapia producers have formed a co-operative, TILACOOP. It is funded through a share of the crop. Its services include supplying fingerlings, sourcing cheaper feed, co-ordinating technical assistance and conducting demand-driven research. As its counterpart in Chile, TILACOOP markets both domestically and internationally.

In sub-Saharan Africa, a review in the early 1990s found that as many as 4 000 co-operatives existed in Nigeria alone with the earliest dating back to1907. However, although numerous, they have not usually been effective because most were mismanaged and politicised (Turtianen and Hussi, 1992). In at least Ghana, Kenya, and Nigeria co-operative legislation needed revision to permit management autonomy from government, and the marketing of crops. The experience from agricultural associations is that when associations have management autonomy and a business reason to exist they can succeed as with the coffee cooperatives in Kenya (Cleaver, 1993). Self-sufficient financially, and paying market interest rates, farmer's associations have been particularly successful in managing shared water supplies in Kenya and Nigeria, and diffusing processing technology. There exist also some farmer-managed co-operative savings and loans associations. Co-operative credit institutions in countries such as Benin, Burundi, Cameroon and Ghana have been most successful; mobilising farmer savings and lending at rates that reflect costs and risk (Cleaver, 1993).

Producer groups and model farmers may be required to assist more with extension services and training (Moehl et al., 1999). Increasingly in sub-Saharan Africa, the cost of separate extension services for agriculture and aquaculture is forcing amalgamation of the two and a unified service. The disadvantage of a unified extension system is that extension workers may be unfamiliar with the less significant sector, aquaculture. To provide adequate technical assistance while minimising public expenditures, extension services focussing on farmer groups and farm leaders could prove advantageous.

Research and Technical Development Policies

Research in aquaculture has two major aspects, including basic and applied research. Where research funds should be spent and who should finance research will vary with the development stage of the species and with the procedures for allocating funds.

Experimentation into species and techniques may occur over several decades, and may not even result in a successful outcome. Three stages are generally defined. Throughout the initial development stage of a species, if positive, returns to research tend to be low. During this stage, not only will research be primarily publicly funded, but also it will usually be limited. This is, in part, because of the relative infancy of the industry and because of the small weight in national economies. In the Philippines, research intensity, as measured by the amount of research spending as a proportion of aquaculture revenues, approximates 0.3% (Olalo, 1999). In Australia the planned figure is 0.5% (Ogburn and Evans, 1998).

During the development stage of a species, funding will be primarily public. This is because research has many features of a common property. Results cannot be retained only by the funding agency. Because research-funding farms cannot appropriate research results, and noncontributing and competing farms enjoy "free-rider" benefits, there is little or no incentive for the private sector to fund research during the development stage (Bjorndal et al., 2000). As a result, the government has to fund research. The rationale for publicly funded research is that it will encourage the establishment of firms and society will enjoy positive externalities. Before it established its farm, Aquacorporación on soils, markets and tilapia cultivation that the public sector produced (Porras, 2000). Also, both Aquacorporacion and smaller commercial farms have adopted monosex tilapia technology that was developed with public funds by INCOPESCA (Instituto Costarricense de Pesca y Acuacultura).

In addition to the amount of money devoted to research, policy -makers can influence the efficacy of the money spent[10]. In sub-Saharan Africa, while aquaculture is a recent introduction, it has been studied at least as far back as the 1940s and 1950s in certain countries (Entsua-Mensah et al., 1999). Yet, the impact of research, as reflected in output, has been limited. The low output can be partly attributed to disregard for economic incentives to producers. However, part of the problem has been poor research co-ordination and problematic diffusion of research results within sub-Saharan Africa (Coche, 1994). A solution proposed has been to establish a regional information network (Coche and Collins, 1997). Another factor affecting research efficiency has been the lack of demand-driven research (Entsua-Mensah et al., 1999). If the agenda is determined by a top-down approach, existing expertise and personal interests will orient publicly funded research. This is not unique to Africa. In Asia, a survey of more than a dozen countries found that most research personnel in aquaculture were biologists, which contributed to the predominance of biological and technical research (FAO-NACA, 1997). The research agenda was supply-driven, which was not in the interest of the industry. Of 330 research projects studied in the survey, more than 80% were oriented to aquaculture technologies and systems. Less than 3% of the remaining total went to areas such as policy, planning, socio-economics and management. To obtain demand-driven research, the private sector has to be involved, either as a source of funds, or as one of the stakeholders setting the research agenda.

After the development stage, there may be a relative decline in publicly funded technical research as profit-driven enterprises internalise the research costs. As the industry expands and retail prices fall, conserving market share and shifting demand upward become increasingly important for the industry. Research focus may then change towards marketing. Marketing research is generally done by private enterprises. In addition, research and technical development are a means of coping with movements down the demand curve. If demand for a product is price elastic, a movement down the demand curve[11] will increase profits if costs fall (Kinnucan, 1995).

According to product cycle theory, initial development of knowledge-intensive industries that produce tradable goods will occur in industrialised countries (Vernon, 1987). This is particularly the case for high-income goods because only those countries will have sufficient middle income consumers to form a market. Over time, however, technology increasingly becomes embodied in purchased equipment and is diffused to other countries, including the developing world. The diffusion of technology will encourage production in low-cost countries, namely developing countries because of their low wages. Ultimately, if there is technological stagnation, developing countries gain comparative advantage. This implies that continued research and development can negate the product cycle and maintain a advantage.

An example where research and development negated the product cycle is salmon farming in Norway. Farmed salmon is an internationally tradable good. Yet, the decline in output from Norway, as suggested in the product cycle model, has not occurred. Most Norwegian farmers have not relocated to developing countries. They have continued to produce domestically because of continued technological advances. Norway has continued to focus research on increasing labour productivity and reducing costs through lower mortality rates, improved feed conversion rates and genetic improvements. This has allowed Norway to maintain, and even increase, output. Preliminary figures suggest that Norwegian output exceeded 390,000 tons in 1999, and its potential output (even with existing sites) has been estimated at 740,000 tons (Hempel, 1995). Technological advances have lowered costs sufficiently to maintain competitive advantage with Norwegian labour productivity increasing from 50 tons to 300 tons per man-year. The real cost of cultivating and processing farmed salmon has more than halved between 1987 and 1998 (Kontali Analyse, 1999). Even a further decline in farm-gate prices of one-third would leave salmon farming in Norway profitable (Hempel, 1995).

A factor that accelerates private research funding is industry consolidation. From more than one thousand Norwegian salmon farmers in the 1980s, the number had fallen to 230 in the mid-1990s (Hempel, 1995). Since then, there has been further consolidation and four producers now dominate Norwegian exports. During the same period, the number of companies involved in Atlantic salmon farming approximately halved in Chile, and declined even faster in Canada and the United Kingdom (Muir et al., 1996). As industries consolidated, they funded more research. Industry structures where farms are perfectly or monopolistically competitive lack excess profits for research. At equilibrium, average revenues equal average costs for the typical farm and excess profits are zero. Moreover, farms in a perfectly competitive industry can sell all they wish at the given price; they have little incentive to innovate. Unlike monopolistic and perfectly competitive farms, oligopolistic farms have both the means to fund research and the incentive to innovate. Often, research can only be undertaken in large discreet units, and oligopolies have the excess profits for private funding. Moreover, demand-driven, the research can provide technological gains and early-mover advantage.

Strategic Planning

Because promotion of aquaculture requires a holistic approach, a strategic plan is useful. It provides a comprehensive set of policies to achieve designated objectives and ensures that inter-related activities, such as agriculture and fisheries, are included, that environmental issues, such as access to water and land, are addressed and that the policy-mix is consistent (Corbin and Young, 1997). One advantage of a strategic plan is to mitigate institutional overlapping of jurisdictions. Where there are several institutions responsible for aquaculture with all the attendant rivalry and duplication, a sector plan can encourage consensus over goals and strategies.

Given the marginal nature of aquaculture in most sub-Saharan countries, it is not surprising that most have no plan. In a review conducted in the early 1990s, most of the then ten SADC-countries did not have a development plan for aquaculture (ALCOM, 1994). A more recent review of some sub-Saharan countries found that, with the exception of Madagascar, there was little aquaculture planning (Moehl et al., 2000).

A "good" plan is a pro-active strategy for the development of the industry and should be realistic and enforceable, with scenarios and policy options. In some jurisdictions, there is multi-year indicative planning in which aquaculture output is projected and a development strategy outlined (OECD, 1989). By providing targets, a strategic plan assists policy-makers in evaluating progress and in indicating where there are bottlenecks. In Madagascar, a physical tonnage is forecasted, which assists policy-makers in evaluating progress. The Master Plan of Aquaculture in Tunisia not only describes the expected supply of cultivated species, but also it develops a strategy for marketing fish species domestically and internationally (Gazbar, 1996).

A plan should, in general, have the following six characteristics. Be relevant and oriented to the industry; openness with other agencies and stakeholders; definition of goals, issues and constraints in meeting the goals and addressing the issues; definition of actions to address issues and accomplish goals; specification of a time frame for actions; have a broad scope; be flexible. A hypothetical development plan is indicated in Table 2 below (FAO-NACA, 1997).

Table 2. A hypothetical development plan

Issue category

Issue

Constraint

Action required

Time frame

Administrative and institutional

Poor enforcement of regulations

Personnel

Rely more on producer associations

Medium term

Technical

Shortage of quality feed

No feed factories
Right mix unknown

Lower tariffs on feed ingredients;

Short term




Research feed

Long term

Socio-economic

Lack of credit

Lack of collateral;
Banks convinced aquaculture is too risky

Encourage land entitlement;
Give loan guarantees

Long term
Medium term

Physical

Shortage of suitable

Limited land and water

Increase productivity of existing sites;
Encourage cage culture

Medium term;
Medium term

Environmental

Pollution


Zoning

Medium term

Human resources

Lack of skilled managers

Training too expensive

Encourage cooperative training programmes

Medium term
Long term

To achieve openness, there are two different approaches: the top-down and the bottom-up. Most countries in Asia use the top-down method. With this approach, central government agencies decide the issues and needs for the industry (FAO-NACA, 1997). With the bottom-up approach, stakeholders are encouraged, through a participatory process, to discuss issues and objectives. In Bangladesh, which uses a bottom-up approach, consultations are with research institutions, NGOs and producer associations. In the Philippines, species are separated (i.e. shrimp, tilapia, and seaweed) and consultations with stakeholders connected with each species are conducted. The advantage of the bottom-up approach is that stakeholders can identify constraints and needs. Another advantage is that the plan is more likely to be implemented because it comes from end users (Neiland et.al., 1998). However, the bottom-up approach is more costly in money, personnel and time.

When formulating a development strategy, an objective analysis of advantages and constraints of the sector is necessary. This enables a jurisdiction to focus on the most competitive sectors. In Hawaii, the process is called ADN (Aquaculture Development Niche) (State of Hawaii, 1993). ADN is defined as a group of broadly based business opportunities that possess similar characteristics and have similar development potential. In ADN, opportunities for species are examined and constraints evaluated. All the pre-requisites for commercial aquaculture development, as discussed previously, are evaluated. This is illustrated in the diagram below.

Figure 1. Illustration of an aquaculture development niche

The advantage of this approach is that it integrates all facets of aquaculture. One is not merely answering the question of how can enough fish be produced to meet the growing demand, but whether production can be sustainable. A holistic approach including ecological considerations reduces the chances of resource use conflicts and resource exhaustion (Greenpeace International, 1999). Zoning can be implemented, and limitations placed on aquaculture development if it is beyond the carrying capacity of an area. Using ADN, Hawaii has assessed aquaculture, ranging from earthen ponds to offshore mariculture and geothermal exploitation. Potential species have also been selected according to the criteria above.

A similar holistic approach to aquaculture planning occurs in Australia, where not only there is a national plan, but also plans for aquaculture development in States and within States exist. The national plan places aquaculture within the context of the food industry and Australia's resources and constraints, suggesting goals and policies (Commonwealth of Australia, 1994) The Aquaculture Committee reviews the plan regularly to identify new priorities[12]. (Gillespie, 1998). This indicates that planning is an on-going process.

There are similar plans within the States, such as the plan for regions Gascoyne and Kimberley in Western Australia (Government of Western Australia, 1999). The potential for aquaculture is examined with possible species prioritised. For each species, the production technology is summarised for its adaptability to the region. It is also specified whether or not research will be needed. The market analysis covers price sensitivity, competition from alternative food sources and market potential. Economic aspects include input costs and economies of scale. Finally, the potential species is judged for its overall suitability. If the species is of high priority, policies to promote its development are recommended. An example is given in Table 3.

Table 3. Example of a holistic approach to aquaculture planning

Species

Technology

Culture system

Market potential

Economic potential

Comments/ Outlook

Eels (Anguilla sp.)

Well established;

Dependent on wild elves

Fresh water
All systems
Pond/tank

No domestic market;
Small export market

Limited profit potential;
Smoked has potential

Need to expand markets;
Little potential

Argyle bream (H. jenkinsis)

Some research needed

Fresh water
All systems
Pond/tank
Polyculture

Very good domestic market;
Export market;
Price elastic

Unknown but probably good;
Asian market very price elastic

Very good candidate;
Production costs are low;
Freezes well;
Fish are robust

For sub-Saharan Africa, a similar plan would focus on assessment of opportunities and constraints. Among the advantages of most countries in sub-Saharan Africa is the existence of indigenous species with a known culture technology in most cases. There are also suitable sites and climatic conditions (Oswald et al., 1996). However, as indicated earlier, most countries suffer enormous constraints. Among these are problems of governance, infrastructure such as transport, availability of quality feed and seed, and access to credit. In addition, in many countries, construction costs are high, as are real interest rates. Policies to deal with the former constraints were discussed in previous sections. The latter constraint indicates that the choice of technology should focus on economic as well as on technical efficiency.

Another advantage is the existence of an unsatisfied domestic market for fish. The Region imports about 1 million tons of fish per year. Over time, growing demand could increase the shortage. Income elasticity of demand for fish in sub-Saharan Africa is positive though less than unity (Delgado and McKenna, 1997). If per capita economic growth continues at historic rates, total demand for fish could increase by 2.7% a year, which is higher than historical world growth rates of 2.0%. Higher real prices of substitutes would still further increase demand. In addition, there is a population factor. With a growth rate of 2.4% a year, Africa's population is projected to reach 1.36 billion by 2025, from 750 million in 1998 (United Nations, 1998). Additional population will result in additional demand for fish. Growing demand and the limited potential for growth of both the marine and inland fisheries could almost double fish imports to 2 million tons by 2010, without any allowance for rising per-capita consumption (FAO, 1996).

While the principal market for farmed finfish in sub-Saharan Africa is the urban domestic market, there is the potential for exports to Europe or North America. For internationally tradable products, transport costs are critical in determining comparative advantage. The price of the delivered product includes both production and transport costs. High transport costs have been a factor impeding the export of fresh tilapia fillets from Fiji to the United States. This was in spite of excellent growing conditions for tilapia (Costa-Pierce, 1998). Sub-Saharan Africa suffers from a disadvantage given its distance from markets in Europe and North America. Load factors, competition and flight frequency are other factors that handicap airfreight from Africa. The cost of air freighting fresh tilapia fillets from Africa to Europe is 8% -40% higher than air freighting from Jamaica to Europe (Carberry, 2000).

However, international transport costs are not an insuperable handicap to successful exporting. In spite of high transport costs, Chilean farmed salmon has a lower delivered price in the United States than its Canadian competitor because higher transport costs are more than offset by lower production costs[13] (Ridler, 1994). Moreover, the processing of fish, with fresh fillets having a 30% price premium over frozen fillets, lessens any transport disadvantage. Zimbabwe's Lake Harvest Aquaculture exports between 10 and 12 tons of fresh tilapia fillets to Europe each week. Planned expansion has a target of more than 50 tons of fillets exported a week. Thus, sub-Saharan Africa may have an absolute disadvantage in exporting whole tilapia but a have a comparative advantage in exporting fresh fillets.

This suggests that a high transport cost-easing strategy in sub-Saharan Africa would have to focus on one or any combination of the following four options. The first option is to focus on a high-valued species that could absorb the cost of freight to major markets in Europe or the United States. Because of its high value, farmed shrimp from Madagascar can be air freighted to the Europe; possibilities to deliver to the United States are under assessment. The second option would be a unique species. This is the case of black pearl oysters exported from French Polynesia to Japan. Another alternative is a processed product that can be transported by ship rather than air, thereby lowering transport costs. This would be a frozen or dried product. The fourth choice could be a processed product that is weight losing. Filleting is weight losing, which lowers costs of air transport and permits fillets to be air freighted fresh (e.g. Nile perch in the case of capture fisheries).

CHAPTER 7. SECTOR-SPECIFIC POLICIES AT THE FARM LEVEL

Rationale for Government Intervention at the Farm Level

While government's intervention in commercial aquaculture at the macro level is self-explanatory, the question arises whether governments should intervene in the industry at the farm level. Commercially produced fish from private farms are not a public good. They belong to the producers. A public good might be the fish from stocking of rivers where there are no riparian property rights. An individual who cannot be excluded from fishing in the waterways does not have the incentive to pay the stocking or rearing costs. So, governments must provide such services. If governments did not provide re-stocking services, waterways might become depleted of fish. The argument for government intervention in commercial aquaculture at the farm level is more complex. As discussed previously, aquaculture can generate negative externalities at the farm level. These may include pollution or the interference of aquaculture with other users of the waterway and land. These spin-offs would not be included in a farm's balance sheet; yet may be an important cost to society.

If property rights were assigned and transaction costs were low, externalities could be solved without government intervention. Those causing negative externalities (such as adverse effects from pollution) would pay compensation to those adversely affected. Compensation would be quantified and enforced through litigation. Often, however, the Coase conditions[14] of assigned property rights and low transaction costs do not apply. Responsibility for damage from non-point sources of pollution is difficult to assign, and transaction costs are often prohibitive. Then, negative spin-offs become difficult to settle through the courts. Thus, government's intervention externalities from commercial aquaculture (tax revenues, foreign exchange earnings, jobs, social amenities) prompts governments to intervene.

Government intervention in aquaculture at the farm level has many facets. In some countries, it has included direct subsidies to producers in the form of start-up grants to kick-start the industry. In others, it has incorporated policies to help the industry expand. In other instances, governments have intervened to shield domestic producers against foreign competition, and help the industry compete internationally. However, it is worth noting that, although they can be effective and even efficient, many of these policies require expenditures. Some may be so onerous that they can be impracticable in the context of fiscal austerity of sub-Saharan Africa. Others do not require direct expenditures, although they have opportunity costs. They may be more appropriate for the region. Thus, these policies must be selectively employed.

Start-up Policies

The extent and type of public intervention in the industry in part depends on the development stage of the industry. As discussed in the previous chapter, commercial aquaculture typically develops in three or four stages (Poxton, 1992). The stage progression is measured by total output. It goes from infancy to growth, maturity and perhaps to decline (Csavas, 1994). In the initial stage, which will normally last for 10-15 years, small projects are developed, often with very little capital. This is the research and development phase. Gradually, if biologically and commercially successful, output expands into the second phase. If the species is internationally tradable, the technology will diffuse to other countries that are potential competitors. During this third phase, there will be rapid expansion followed by a slower growth. The final phase could be a decline in output as price declines force less efficient operations to leave the industry.

Government financial assistance, in the form of start-up funding, may be critical in the first and second phases. The argument for start-up funding in the first and second phases is that aquaculture, as an "infant industry", may need support until it reaches a stage at which costs are competitive. The need to assist infant industries has been recognised at least since Hamilton in the eighteenth century. If industries learn by doing, costs will decline with experience, and so the argument goes, such industries need government assistance in their early years. Such assistance may be in the form of research, start-up costs, or tariff and non-tariff protection. With maturity will come economies of scale and international competitiveness. Then, in theory, government assistance should end.

Reinforcing the argument for government assistance is the inability of infant industries to obtain private funding. Financial institutions are naturally prudent. Faced with biological and other uncertainties, they are unwilling to provide credit until risks are known. Without bank loans, development will be slow. Government funding to such infant industries is then not a substitute for private funding because the latter will only occur as the industry matures.

To ease financial constraints, start-up funding is often provided to farmers in the form of cash grants. In salmon farming, most countries provided start-up funding to producers. In Norway, there were regional grants. There was also a tax exemption, which was equivalent to a government loan of approximately US$400 000 per farm (Heen, 1993). This encouraged expansion, enabling Norway to maintain its leadership in the industry. In eastern Canada, twenty-one salmon farms received each approximately US$50 000 in cash grants to supplement their equity financing. They also received publicly provided extension services and research. An ex post evaluation of the cash grant component found that discounted net benefits of providing start-up funding were positive (Ridler, 1998). However, many African countries in sub-Saharan Africa lack the resources to provide initial grants and monitoring personnel.

Rather than cash grants, an alternative form of start-up funding is to issue bonds. For governments, bond financing has the advantage of not requiring immediate cash outlays. In Connecticut, United States, commercial oyster farming developed through an initial bond authorisation in 1987 (Volk, 1998). Farmers obtained their leases through competitive bidding. The money from the initial and later bond issues has allowed the leases to be planted with seed. In addition to initial funds raised from the bond issues, farmers pay 10% of the sale value of the harvest to sustain the planting. Benefits in terms of jobs and incomes have greatly exceeded the amount governments must repay on the bonds (Volk, 1998). Bond financing could be a possible option in certain countries of sub-Saharan Africa.

Expansionary Policies

Once aquaculture has taken off, often farmers experience difficulties to expand. In sub-Saharan Africa, several constraints impede the development of commercial aquaculture. The most important ones include availability and high cost of inputs. Inputs referred to here include feed, seeds, and capital. There are specific policies that governments can undertake to address these issues.

Policies Dealing with Unavailability of Inputs

Absence or limited availability of necessary inputs may prove a serious impediment to the development of aquaculture. Often, it is more critical than cost. Government policies that are aimed at assisting farmers to overcome the issue shall target the increase in supply of the limited/lacking input.

Availability of good quality feed is important because, in most commercial operations, feed accounts for more than half the operating costs. In most sub-Saharan countries, the limited demand for fish feed and the high cost of agricultural by-products have handicapped the development of a fish feed industry, although there are exceptions (Entsua-Mensah, 1999). In Nigeria, Malawi and Zambia, large farms produce their own fish feed. One policy to develop a feed industry is to encourage investment in aquaculture from a large farm. By its size, Aquacorporación in Costa Rica production, and feed companies developed. At Man in Côte d'Ivoire, there is a plan to generate sufficient demand for a private feed mill from small and medium-scale project commercial farms. However, the project is externally funded; the strategy of relying on small-scale farms to generate demand for quality feed may not be transferable to non-donor funded aquaculture.

An alternative policy is to encourage livestock companies to diversify into aquaculture and feed production. In Jamaica, the Jamaica Broilers Group diversified from poultry to fish. In Thailand, two large poultry-feed producing companies, CP and Laem Thong, diversified from poultry to shrimp. Not only did they start producing shrimp feed, but the companies extended their experience of contract farming from poultry to shrimp (Tokrisna, 1999). In Madagascar, a company specialised in livestock feed production is producing shrimp feed on an experimental basis.

If feed can be imported, but at the cost of foreign exchange, import substitution policies may be desirable. In the Philippines, a domestic feed industry has developed as a result of levying tariffs on imports of feed and feed ingredients. To encourage domestic production, initially, 30% and 10% tariffs were respectively levied. Because tariffs raise production costs, there was concern that tilapia exports could shrink. Thus, tariffs have since been lowered to 10% and 3% in order to lower feed prices. However, as is common with protectionist policies, the new domestic feed producers have resisted complete elimination of the tariffs (Olalo, 1999).

As with feed production, the availability of seed in sub-Saharan Africa, especially fingerlings, faces issues of quantity and quality. Reproducibility of tilapia is high in that the species can easily be reproduced in captivity and without high technology. Initially, catfish required hatchery techniques, but now farmer-friendly techniques are possible (Moehl et al., 1999). To ensure enough seed supply and maintain high quality fingerlings, an appropriate policy would be to induce a number of farmers to specialise in seed production and to train them in modern hatchery techniques. Initially, a few government stations could be used for broodstock, but increasingly, the private sector will have to replace the stations as a source of fingerlings for small-scale rural aquaculture and commercial operations.

Commercial aquaculture has high capital needs. With industrial techniques, the need is for start-up fixed capital. The need is also for operating capital to cover cash-flow shortages. Unfortunately, in sub-Saharan Africa, financial institutions are reluctant to provide credit to aquaculture. One of the arguments against lending to aquaculturists is that, in most countries aquaculture is either new, or unknown, with risks unquantified. The problem is compounded by past negative experience. For example, in the 1980s, as part of its policy to encourage fish farming, the government in Ghana instructed banks to lend money for pond construction. Unfortunately, poor management and inappropriate technology caused many farms to default. The repercussions were still felt in 1990s, with bankers insisting on physical assets as collateral. The value of the collateral was to at least equal the amount of the loan (Wijkström, 1990). The lack of collateral remains one of the major factors blocking aquaculture farmers access to loans[15]. In other countries, the lack of reliable business plans has deterred banks from lending to aquaculture farmers. Instant consultants appeared to assist with business plans that proved unreliable. The result has been a high degree of scepticism among lenders[16]. Lending was also often politicised, at negative real interest rates and with little regard to loan recovery (Cleaver, 1993).

To increase accessibility of commercial farms to bank credit, a number of policy options exist. One policy is to demonstrate to bankers that commercial farms that are financially viable exist. By demonstrating the actual profitability of aquaculture, the intention is to create awareness of the sector and encourage lending. The banks targeted should be those which have a high ratio of their loan portfolio in agriculture, and are responsive to alternative agriculture. Banks that are open to alternative agriculture appear to be the most likely to also lend to commercial aquaculture (Bacon et al., 1998). Such targeting of credit to a sub-sector has succeeded in China, Japan and Korea (Cleaver, 1993).

An alternative or a complementary policy is to have business plans evaluated for their technical merits by government officials. That reassures bankers who lack aquaculture expertise. This practice has produced good results in Madagascar. Another policy is to involve bankers from the beginning of the project rather than wait until a loan is needed because of financial need (Mellac, 1995).

If financial institutions remain reluctant to lend, government loan guarantees are possible. They address the issue of collateral. With government loan guarantees, the risk of default by the borrower is passed from banks to taxpayers. Among OECD countries, Canada Holland and Spain have encouraged commercial aquaculture with loan guarantees (OECD, 1989).

Policies Dealing with High Cost of Inputs

If the high cost, rather than availability of inputs, is a principal constraint to the commercial sector's viability, the industry may never be sustainable. The industry may illustrate a lack of absolute advantage vis-à-vis other such as farmed shrimp, high seed and feed costs can place sub-Saharan Africa at a competitive disadvantage compared to Asian shrimp producers. For tilapia production, sub-Saharan Africa has a feed cost disadvantage compared to Latin America. Subsidising inputs can be both costly and inefficient. In the Philippines, fertiliser production has been subsidised since the 1970s, but the high fiscal cost and resulting distortions have forced its curtailment. Subsidies may also discourage the private sector. Government stations that provide free or subsidised fingerlings create a disincentive to private investment in hatcheries. However, if the conclusion is that after support during infancy input costs will fall, perhaps because of economies of scale or of scope, input subsidies can be temporarily targeted towards the industry. Policies that lead to increased supply of feed and seed may also lessen the problem of high costs.

An input that has commonly been subsidised is financial credit. Financial capital is not only scarce in sub-Saharan Africa, but it is also expensive. With economic reform, distortions in financial markets have been reduced, with artificially low interest rates increasingly replaced by lending rates that reflect capital scarcity and expected inflation. Interest rates, both nominal and real, can therefore be high particularly for ventures such as aquaculture for which risks are often unknown. In addition to providing start-up funds to eliminate or lessen the need to borrow, a policy that has been widely followed in many countries has been providing an interest rate subsidy. France, Greece, Jamaica, Portugal and Spain are among countries that have used this policy to promote aquaculture. In Jamaica, the Inland Fisheries Unit initially provided funding to producers at reduced rates to encourage pond construction. Over time, however, credit arrangements were between farmers and retailers, or between farmers and input suppliers (Wint, 1996). An indirect social cost of interest rate subsidies is to bias the choice of production techniques. Where there is elasticity of technical substitution, lowering the cost of capital (vis-à-vis other technology with higher capital-labour ratios. However, interest rate subsidies are preferable to cash grants because the burden of default falls on the producer as well as the taxpayer.

Export Promotion Policies

Aquaculture expansion may be international (if the species is internationally traded), and may cause a dynamic evolution of market shares internationally. From wooden cages and moist-feed, and from high mortality rates and poor feed conversion rates, the salmon farming industry has expanded globally, spawning continual technological advances. Usually, in this expansion stage, there is little role for direct government assistance. However, government intervention may be needed to make the industry maintain its share of the international market.

If acceptable under international trade agreements, policies to encourage exports are less distortionary than import substitution policies[17]. They mainly consist of economic incentives such as tax exemptions, tax holidays and import duties. While economic incentives basically are used as an attractive magnet for foreign investment in the sector, they can, at the same time, stimulate exports. Although taxes rank below governance and stability as determinants of business investment in Africa, they are a major grievance (Sachs, 1998). When questioned about grievances, business executives in Africa cite taxes as either the major problem (domestic companies) or as the second most important problem (foreign companies). Therefore, tax relief can be an effective incentive. For governments, tax relief has the advantage of incurring no direct expenditures although there is the cost of lost revenues.

Such incentives may be obligatory if competing countries offer tax exemptions. Unlike many South American countries, Ecuador does not offer tax exemptions on inputs for shrimp farmers, which puts them at a competitive disadvantage a (Cámera Nacional, 1999). To provide a "fair playing field" for its exporters, Ecuador has exempted 43 shrimp farms from payment on part of corporate taxes.

Governments may allow companies a period of grace before corporation taxes are levied. This period is referred to as a tax holiday. In Costa Rica, companies, including the foreign Aquacorporacion Internacional, are exempt from corporate taxes for 10 to 15 years (Hishamunda, 2000a). In Puerto Rico where aquaculture is a priority sector, farms receive 90% tax holidays for up to twenty years (Wint, 1991). In Iran, where the private sector has an increasing role in the production of carp and rainbow trout, the 80 private rainbow farms that were operational in 1996 received not only preferential loans and a feed subsidy but also tax free status for twenty years (Rana, 1997).

In Sri Lanka, aquaculture is recent with virtually no output until 1980 (Siriwardena, 1999). A few large multinational companies, and some small-scale farms, started shrimp farming in the early 1980s; by mid 1990s, more than 3 000 tons was being exported. However, in 1996 disease closed 90% of all shrimp farms. Only 25% restarted and the Sri Lankan government has offered a number of incentives to revive the industry. Farms enjoy five years tax holiday and a tax discount for fifteen years after the tax holiday. Farms are also exempt from duty on imports and turnover taxes, and from exchange controls. Banks also offer discounts on loan rates and accept deferred payments. To be entitled to this tax relief, farms have to export at least 90% of their production. Thus the strategy is both to revive shrimp farming and provide incentives to export. In Madagascar, export-oriented shrimp farming enterprises, most of which operate in industrial free-trade zones, have several benefits. They are exempt from import duties, consumption, transaction, export, professional and excise taxes. They are given tax holidays on dividends for 15 years, period after which a 10% tax is levied (Hishamunda, 2000c).

Tax exemptions may extend to duties on imported inputs. They may allow remission of permit fees. In Honduras, as a stimulus to the sector, aquaculture is exempt from taxes on imported machinery, equipment, brood stock, larva feed and fertiliser. Processing plants do not pay taxes on exports or imports (Morales, 2000). In Costa Rica, companies that export outside Central America enjoy a number of exemptions. Sales taxes, custom duty, stabilisation taxes, and local taxes are among some of the exemptions exporters enjoy. Aquacorporación Internacional also 15% of the fob value of exports (Porras, 2000). In the Philippines, where aquaculture policy is outward looking in that the sector is valued more for its contribution to exports than for its satisfaction of the domestic demand, investment is encouraged if it is export oriented.

Aquaculture companies that have more than 40% foreign ownership can benefit from incentives provided that at least 70% of output is exported (Olalo, 1999). For domestic companies, the minimum exports must be 50%. In addition, export taxes and permit costs are reduced.

Summary

This part of the report discussed non-sector and sector-specific policies that can be used to promote commercial aquaculture. Under non-sector specific policies, governance is recognised as a key ingredient in attracting investors to commercial aquaculture and in influencing long term economic growth. Good governance reassures investors that their capital is secure and offers an incentive for further investment. Stability, political and policy, is of particular concern to investors in sub-Saharan Africa. Enabling policies such as guaranteed rights to land usage if not land ownership, and an appropriate exchange rate, are all factors that encourage investment. Recent data show that those countries in sub-Saharan Africa that undertook administrative reforms have experienced higher growth. Some of these reforms included openness to trade and emphasis on the private sector as source of wealth creation.

There are some aquaculture specific policies governments in sub-Saharan Africa could use to regulate the development of the industry. The main ones include zoning and the obligation to acquire permits to establish farms. A general principle is to have a legislative framework compatible with monitoring and enforcement constraints, and which will ensure environmental sustainability. Over-regulation should be avoided; it can be detrimental to the industry, and is fiscally costly.

Most countries in sub-Saharan Africa lack specific aquaculture legislation. Yet, the absence of legislation can be a deterrent to investors because it creates uncertainty. The problem is compounded when obtaining regulatory permission is administratively cumbersome. Where no legislation exists, laws relating to land and water access for pond aquaculture could be modelled on those for agriculture.

To administer the sector, a co-ordinating lead agency is optimal. Given the marginal nature of aquaculture in sub-Saharan Africa, such a specialised agency is implausible. A co-ordinating committee composed of personnel from different departments could be an interim arrangement. It could develop an information sheet describing what requirements are needed for a permit and where forms can be obtained. The committee could have responsibility for processing the permit, alleviating duplicating reviews. Economic incentives and self-policing can complement command and control of aquaculture development.

Whenever possible, research and development/extension should be conducted by the private sector and co-ordinated by producer associations. The advantage of producer associations coordinating research is that the results of the research can be internalised to all members thereby giving an incentive to contribute research funds.

In much of the sub-Saharan countries, many government stations have been abandoned, which has prompted many experts to recommend that they be divested of their role as seed producers, as suppliers of food fish and as demonstration centres. Fingerling production would become the responsibility of the private sector. The method of privatisation depends on equity as well as efficiency. An auction or direct sale might exclude local communities. Where there is community interest a preferable method is a joint venture with scheduled disengagement by the government.

An appropriate strategy where access to bank loans is difficult is to encourage investment by large farms. In fact where there are a number of constraints to aquaculture, large operations may be essential to support small-scale farming These could be an agribusiness that has the "know-how" to produce its own feed, and to market its output abroad. By its success it should entice new entrants into the industry, or at least establish sharecropping. Large farms could be domestic or foreign.

Many producer associations have been politicised and mismanaged yet they can be instrumental in promoting the industry. Well-managed and accountable producer associations should be encouraged. They are a medium for lobbying and diffusing technical know-how. They should also be used as marketing agents, and as monitors for environmental self-policing.

These and other policies are summarised in Table 4 for a quick reference. The list is not exhaustive, but covers some of the more widely implemented policies for aquaculture promotion. Many require additional expenditures, and although they can be effective and even efficient, they may be impracticable in the context of fiscal austerity of sub-Saharan Africa. Others require no extra financial outlays, although there will be opportunity costs such as lost tax revenues; these may be more appropriate for the Region. Because a time frame should be part of a plan, the list of policies indicates whether their impact on output is immediate (within one year), medium -term (1-5 years) or long-term (more than five years).

Table 4. Indicative list of policies that could be used to promote commercial aquaculture

Constraint/Issue

POLICY INSTRUMENTS

Involving additional outlays

Impact

Not involving additional outlays

Impact

Reduce Administrative duplication

Lead agency
Sectoral plan

Long
Medium

Legislative framework for aquaculture

Medium

Ease permit applications

   

Improve access to regulations

Medium

Expedite processing of applications

Medium

Encourage environmental sustainability

   

Land/water legislation

Long

Legislation on imports of alien species

Long

Environmental Impact Assessment

Long

Self policing

Medium

Economic incentives

Medium

Zoning

Long term

Availability of feed

Subsidise feed mills

Long

Attract a large firm with a demand for feed

Long

Encourage livestock firms to diversify

Medium

Encourage domestic production with tariffs

Medium

Availability of seed

Use of government fish stations

Short

Disinvestiture of stations to the private sector

Medium

Availability of land

Aquaculture Estates

Medium

Zoning

Medium

Culture systems other than pond culture (if possible)

Short

Availability of bank credit

Loan guarantees(default involves outlays)

Medium

Involve bankers at the beginning of the project

Medium

Transaction cost subsidies

Medium

Credible business plans

Medium

Have departmental personnel vet business plans

Medium

Generate and diffuse info. about the profitability of aquaculture

Medium

Guaranteed land rights (for collateral)

Medium

Cost of bank credit

Start-up grant

Short

   

Loan subsidy

Medium

   

Cost of feed/seed

Subsidies
Cash grants

Short
Short

Exemption from sales taxes/custom duties on inputs

Medium

Promotion of investment

Start-up grant

Short

Tax holidays

Medium

Export subsidies

Tax relief on imports

Medium

Medium

Tax relief from other taxes

Medium

Medium

Encourage foreign investors

   

Currency convertibility

Medium

Capital/ profit repatriat.

Medium

Debt/equity swaps

Medium

Joint ventures

Medium

Taxes exemptions

Medium

Marketing

Market agent

Medium

Product promotion by producer associations


Direct marketing

Medium


Medium

Market outlets

Long



Introduce species

Medium



Research

Increase research intensity

Long

Increase demand driven research

Medium

Improve diffusion, and networks

Long

Increase private sector funding

Medium

Training and extension

Extension based on model farmers

Medium

Training/extension provided by the firms supplying inputs

Medium

Training at colleges/ professional schools

Long

Training/extension provided by the producer associations

Medium

Use of technical assistance paid for by producers

Medium


[9] The role of the Chilean government was that of a facilitator. The exchange rate was on a sliding peg to avoid over-valuation, thereby facilitating exports. Except for distance limitations between farm sites, regulations including those covering the import of salmon eggs, was at a minimum.
[10] Estimating research efficiency requires calculating consumer and producer surpluses and attributing market changes to research (Kabir and Ridler, 1989). This depends on the demand and supply elasticities of the species, on the commercial stage of the species and on the diffusion of research.
[11] Following an outward shift in supply.
[12] The Plan identified ten areas for strategic management. The ten areas were: industry structure and organisation; the relationship between aquaculture and the capture fisheries; government framework; environmental management; land and water planning; research and development; marketing and product development; education and training; extension services; and quarantine and movement.
[13] Labour, feed and seed costs are low in Chile; they compensate for freight charges.
[14] Coase argued that assigned property rights and low transaction costs obviate the need for government intervention in reducing negative externalities. These two conditions are referred to as the "Coase Conditions".
[15] In some countries such as Canada, the reluctance to lend money was compounded by legislation, which precluded underwater animals from being considered as collateral.
[16] Problems with bank credit are not unique to aquaculture. There has been widespread credit failure in agriculture projects, particularly with parastatal credit institutions.
[17] Readers/users of this document are advised to consult appropriate documentation from the World Trade Organisation on subsidies and countervailing measures.

Previous Page Top of Page Next Page