Previous Page Table of Contents Next Page


Part Three
Factors and Imputs for Agricultural
Production: Structures and Institutions in Syria

CHAPTER 11
The Syrian Agricultural Producers:
Structural and Distributional Features
by Alexander Sarris and Alessandro Corsi

11.1 Introduction: Types of farmers in Syria

The main production units in Syrian agriculture are small- and medium-sized farmers, as the agrarian reform caused the practical disappearance of traditional large-scale landowners. The purpose of this chapter is to illustrate the various structural and distributional characteristics of these farmers. The main source of structural information on Syrian agriculture, the agricultural censuses, report farmers in terms of “holders” who, according to the census definition, are the persons responsible for technical and administrative investment of the agricultural holding, and who have the ultimate economic responsibility on their own or with partners.

During the period between the agricultural censuses of 1981 and 1994, there has been a considerable 26 percent increase in the total number of holders, from 485 691 in 1981 to 613 657 in 1994 (Table 11.1).

Table 11.1 Farm holders in Syria and proportion with main job farming


Census year

1981

1994

Total number of holders (1)

485 691

613 657

Holders with land (2)

409 492

573 193

Holders without land (3)

76 199

40 464

Holders with land with main job farming (4)

261 386

409 142

Holders without land with main job farming (5)

11 224

22 860

(4) as share of (2) (%)

63.8

71.4

(5) as share of (3) (%)

14.7

56.5

Source: Computed from 1981 and 1994 census of agriculture.

Given that the total cultivable land has not changed by much during this period, the inevitable conclusion is that there has been considerable fragmentation and subdivision of farms, despite laws and regulations that explicitly forbid it. This must have been the consequence of population growth coupled with long standing social norms in Syria that dictate the roughly even subdivision of land among a family’s children.

Holders are divided into those having and those not having land, further classified according to farming being or not being their main occupation. Holders whose main occupation is not farming, a category including absentee owners as well as part-time farmers with a prevalent non-farming occupation, have a considerable importance in Syria. Nevertheless, their number and share have declined: census figures indicate that they were 213 000 (43.9 percent of total holders) in 1981, and 182 000 (29.6 percent) in 1994, while in the same period the number of holders with main job farming had increased from 273 000 to 432 000 (Table 11.1).

The category of holders whose main occupation is not farming can be considered to be composed mostly of absentee owners, included in the category “holders with land with main job not in farming”. Several waves of out-migration have actually increased their number. In fact, the category includes members of the urban middle classes with some agricultural property, but also relatively poor farmers unable to make a living out of agriculture and attracted by better opportunities in neighboring countries or in the cities. In the 1980s, electrification and improved road links in rural areas permitted a gradual return to the villages of many holders as part-time farmers who regularly commute to cities, even at substantial distances in all peri-urban areas in the country. Part-time farmers enjoy all the benefits of full-time farmers in terms of Government services and subsidized inputs. The return to their home base of many part-time farmers may also be a partial explanation for the phenomenon of increasing conflicts between owners and operating farmers, where the former want to recover possession of their property and the latter are not willing to terminate the existing sharecropping or labour agreements. Hence, the phenomenon of return to the land may have side effects on an already saturated land and labour market.

The proportion of holders with main jobs in agriculture varies considerably by region, as table 11.2 illustrates. The proportions are generally higher among those holders that have land, and also higher in regions that are mostly rural like Al-Rakka, Deir-ez-Zor, and Al-Hassakeh. This supports the thesis that proximity to urban areas leads to more part-time farming. The educational status of holders is very low. More than 83 percent of all holders have education less than or equal to elementary, and a large share of those (44 percent) are illiterate.

While the total number of farm holders with and without land is known, there are many categories within these broad groups. It is possible to group households partaking in farm operations, and agricultural production in general, into many overlapping functional categories. These are:

(a) landed holders whose main occupation is not farming (mainly absentees);

(b) landed holders with farming as a main occupation, i.e. owner-operators;

(c) landless holders whose main occupation is not farming (mainly absentees);

(d) landless holders with farming as a main occupation, i.e. owner-operators without land;

(e) sharecroppers and tenants on private land having a written or oral agreement with the owner of the land;

(f) land reform beneficiaries and state land distribution beneficiaries that do not yet fully own their land. These are owner-like possessors of holdings assigned to them, for which they pay a yearly fee up to concurrence of one-fourth of the value of the assigned land;

(g) tenants on public land, renting on lands belonging to the old state land establishment or to the expropriated land reform areas not distributed to beneficiaries;

(h) squatters on public land - a category of workers aiming at becoming legal tenants and for which regularization is on-going;

(i) squatters on private land, who are mainly sharecroppers whose contract has expired and whose rights are awaiting arbitration;

(j) labourers on state farms, joint ventures or larger private farms with a permanent contract, which is a very small category as most contracts are for short-term casual labour;

(k) landless and near landless labourers, mainly descending from small owner or sharecropping households with inadequate land base to redistribute to children;

(l) agricultural entrepreneurs, these operators rent or own large areas of land, especially in the northeast part of the country.

Table 11.2 Regional distribution of holders (landed, landless, by main job and education)

MOHAFAZA

1981

1994

Total number of holders

Total number of holders

Holders having no land

Holders having land

% Holders with main job Agriculture

% Holders with elementary or lower education

without land

with land

without land

with land

Damascus


7 367

293

7 074

55.3

46.0

75.4

52.6

Damascus Rural

37 608*

41 492

4 473

37 019

57.4

64.9

83.3

81.9

Homs

40 107

50 370

4 383

45 987

53.3

65.3

81.3

76.4

Hama

51 063

65 909

5 030

60 879

57.4

75.9

83.9

81.3

Tartous

42 278

58 773

694

58 079

54.0

53.5

69.6

69.4

Lattakia

36 525

48 208

774

47 434

49.1

60.7

75.7

73.5

Idleb

46 985

55 654

2 476

53 178

52.2

73.3

82.2

84.2

Aleppo

85 927

96 832

7 465

89 367

51.4

78.7

91.9

91.1

Al-Rakka

21 598

27 824

2 300

25 524

58.0

85.2

90.2

92.7

Deir-ez-Zor

29 525

42 042

2 787

39 255

63.2

88.4

91.2

93.0

Al-Hassakeh

55 162

61 089

6 061

55 028

62.1

86.0

90.0

89.8

Al-Sweida

15 792

23 286

1 128

22 158

64.5

61.0

78.2

73.9

Dara'a

20 857

30 432

2 074

28 358

57.8

59.8

81.2

78.4

Quneitra

2 264

4 379

526

3 853

46.6

55.4

66.3

73.8

Total Country

485 691

613 657

40 464

573 193

56.5

71.4

85.8

82.2

*Includes Damascus city.

Source: Computed from 1994 census of agriculture.

However, these groups can be overlapping. For instance one household’s members may be owner operators in one holding and sharecroppers in another, or farm labourers. That is, the groups are not discrete and also their interests often overlap. From the management point of view, apart from absentee owners in categories (a) and (c), and categories (j) and (k), who are permanent and casual labour working under instructions, all other categories function as farm operating households with different degrees of independence from the ultimate owner of the land.

The importance of different types of tenure is exhibited in Table 11.3.

Table 11.3 Landed holders and average holding land size by types of tenure (1994)

MOHAFAZAT

Landed holders

Holders that own all their land

Holders that rent all their land

Holders with other types of tenure

Holders with several types of tenure

No. of holders

Average area (ha)

No. of holders

Average area (ha)

No. of holders

Average area

No. of holders

Average area (ha)

Total Country

573 193

514 752

7.6

19 310

14.2

18 713

9.4

20 418

15.7

Damascus

7 074

6 707

2.8

180

2.1

88

2.0

99

3.4

Damascus Rural

37 019

34 058

3.1

603

4.0

1 333

4.3

1 025

8.3

Homs

45 987

40 832

7.1

2 102

16.2

1 028

6.6

2 025

22.6

Hama

60 879

52 817

6.3

2 426

11.0

2 918

5.5

2 718

12.3

Tartous

58 079

5 6631

1.8

224

1.2

482

1.7

742

2.9

Lattakia

47 434

45 399

2.0

285

1.4

920

1.4

830

2.9

Idleb

53 178

50 487

5.3

337

5.9

958

6.9

1 396

7.2

Aleppo

89 367

83 373

11.9

2 542

14.0

1 929

11.4

1 523

19.1

Al-Rakka

25 524

18 002

28.0

2 507

18.0

2 891

18.2

2 124

26.0

Deir-ez-Zor

39 255

32 331

3.4

2 577

19.0

548

4.0

3 799

12.0

Al-Hassakeh

55 028

41 943

17.6

4 836

15.6

5 328

11.3

2 921

26.2

Al-Sweida

22 158

21 925

7.5

33

6.2

39

2.9

161

14.3

Dara'a

28 358

26 770

7.0

605

2.7

108

5.5

875

8.4

Quneitra

3 853

3 477

4.7

53

4.8

143

4.5

180

8.1

Source: Computed from 1994 census of agriculture.

It can be seen that among holders that have land, the overwhelming proportion (90 percent) consists of holders that own all their land. However, the average size of land operated by landed holders differs according to types of tenure. The largest average land holdings are operated by holders who either rent all land, or operate under a multitude of tenure arrangements. Nevertheless, the conclusion seems to be that the dominant type of holder in Syria is the landed owner operator. These owner operators include those that have received land under the land reform, but have not as yet fully paid for it. In Al-Sweida, Lattakia and Tartous the share of holders that own all their land is the largest: Lattakia and Tartous are areas of traditionally small and intensive farms, while the average farm size in Al-Sweida is around the national average. By contrast, in Al-Rakka and Hassakeh an appreciable part of holders either rent all of their land or have a mixed type of tenure: in both Mohafazat the average farm size is much larger than the national average.

11.2 Size distribution of holdings

The actual size levels can diverge when measured in terms of total area, cultivable area, or actually cultivated area. In addition, the total number of holdings may or may not include holdings without land. The notion of holding stretches across private and public land, it includes a large number of small farms but also large-scale state farms as well as commercial type joint ventures. Seven joint ventures with mixed private and public financing existed in year 2000 with a total of 7 242 ha and an average of 1 035 ha. The average size of holdings in 1994 was 7.6 ha, and this has been decreasing over time, from 11.8 ha in 1970 and 9.6 in 1981. This decrease is a result of the increase in the number of holdings over time, without increase in the total cultivable land.

The evolution of farm size has been different over the national territory. Against a decrease between 1970 and 1981 and then a further decrease in 1994 of average farm size, there are examples of dramatic decreases as in Damascus rural, Homs, Hama, Deir-ez-Zor, Al-Hassakeh, Sweida, Dara’a and Quneitra where average holding size decreased substantially between 1970 and 1994. On the other hand, very small holdings were and continue to prevail in the coastal region. In Tartous, for instance, the already small average holding of 2.7 ha in 1970 only decreased to 1.8 ha in 1994, meaning that some sort of minimum threshold of operation had been reached. There are, however, also cases such as Al-Rakka, where an above national average of holding of 22.1 ha in 1970 increased to 23.6 in 1994, probably indicating some land consolidation (table 11.4).

Table 11.4 Average area (ha) of all holdings in 1970, 1981 and 1994

MOHAFAZAT

1970

1981

1994

Country Total

11.8

9.6

7.6

Damascus city

6.9

6.9

2.7

Damascus rural

3.8

4.7

2.9

Homs

12.6

8.4

7.5

Hama

10.0

7.9

6.2

Tartous

2.7

2.2

1.8

Lattakia

2.4

1.9

1.9

Idleb

6.7

5.4

5.2

Aleppo

14.2

10.9

11.1

Al Rakka

22.1

30.0

23.6

Deir-ez-Zor

9.5

4.4

4.9

Al Hassakeh

36.9

25.5

15.6

Al Sweida

12.2

8.4

7.2

Dara’a

13.2

9.6

6,5

Quneitra

8.6

5.2

4.3

Source: Forni (2001), Sarris (1995), and elaboration from1994 census of agriculture.

The size distribution of holdings that have land in each Mohafazat (the administrative divisions of the country), and the percentage of land operated in each class, are shown in Table 11.5.

Table 11.5 Size distribution of landed holdings in each class, and total land operated

percent 1994

Holding size classes (ha)

<0.5

0.5-2

2-10

10-50

>50

Total

Total number of holders and area (ha)

Damascus City

Holders

30.6

36.2

25.5

7.1

0.6

100.0

7 074

Area

2.7

10.8

31.8

40.4

14.4

100.0

19 868

Rural Damascus

Holders

20.4

37.5

35.6

6.2

0.3

100.0

37 019

Area

1.7

12.3

45.8

31.7

8.4

100.0

122 041

Homs

Holders

7.4

28.3

43.0

18.9

2.4

100.0

45 987

Area

0.3

3.8

23.2

46.4

26.2

100.0

378 195

Hama

Holders

5.1

25.3

52.7

15.3

1.6

100.0

60 889

Area

0.2

4.1

32.5

45.0

18.1

100.0

408 241

Tartous

Holders

18.9

51.7

28.3

1.0

0.0

100.0

58 079

Area

3.1

30.3

55.8

8.0

2.9

100.0

105 225

Lattakia

Holders

18.4

48.9

31.2

1.5

0.0

100.0

47 434

Area

3.1

27.3

58.1

10.3

1.2

100.0

92 752

Idleb

Holders

5.8

31.0

48.9

13.7

0.6

100.0

53 078

Area

0.3

6.6

40.8

44.5

7.8

100.0

288 235

Aleppo

Holders

1.4

11.7

49.5

34.8

2.6

100.0

89 367

Area

0.0

1.2

21.9

58.3

18.6

100.0

1 076 526

Al-Rakka

Holders

0.9

11.5

35.1

39.2

13.3

100.0

25 524

Area

0.0

0.2

2.5

73.5

23.8

100.0

1 635 855

Deir-ez-Zor

Holders

11.5

37.1

37.9

12.5

0.9

100.0

39 255

Area

0.6

7.7

29.5

46.0

16.2

100.0

205 206

Al-Hassakeh

Holders

0.3

3.2

34.0

57.7

4.7

100.0

55 021

Area

0.0

0.2

11.2

66.5

22.1

100.0

951 705

Sweida

Holders

4.8

22.0

51.1

21.1

1.0

100.0

22 158

Area

0.2

3.7

33.8

51.9

10.5

100.0

166 449

Dara'a

Holders

9.4

19.2

52.1

18.7

0.5

100.0

28 358

Area

0.4

3.6

40.3

49.5

6.2

100.0

197 504

Quneitra

Holders

7.8

30.3

46.2

15.3

0.3

100.0

3 853

Area

0.5

6.9

40.6

48.4

3.6

100.0

18 727

Syria

Holders

8.6

27.1

41.6

20.7

2.0

100.0

573 193

Area

0.3

3.7

23.3

49.7

23.0

100.0

4 687 546

Source: Computed from 1994 census of agriculture.

It can be seen that the size distribution of holdings is quite skewed. In 1994, 35.7 percent of landed holdings operated less than 2 ha, but they accounted for only 4 percent of total land operated. By contrast the 2 percent of the largest holdings, namely those with land larger than 50 ha, operated 23 percent of total land of all holdings. The next largest class, namely those operating between 10 and 50 ha, while constituting 20.7 of all holders, operated on almost half the total land. The geographical size distribution of holdings is quite marked, with Tartous and Lattakia being characterized by distributions concentrated in small holdings, while Aleppo, Al-Rakka and Al-Hassakeh are characterized by distributions markedly skewed toward larger size classes.[82]

Table 11.6 presents the distribution of size classes across the geographical regions in 1994. It can be verified, as in the former table, that the bulk of small farms are in rural Damascus, Tartous and Lattakia, while the bulk of the largest holdings are in Aleppo, Al-Rakka, and Al-Hassakeh.

Table 11.6 Size distribution (%) of holdings across Mohafazat in 1994

Holding classes by size (ha)

<0.5

0.5-2

2-10

10-50

>50

Total

Damascus City

4.4

1.6

0.8

0.4

0.4

1.2

Rural Damascus

15.3

8.9

5.5

2.0

1.0

6.5

Homs

7.0

8.4

8.3

7.3

9.5

8.0

Hama

6.3

9.9

13.5

7.9

8.1

10.6

Tartous

22.4

19.3

6.9

0.5

0.2

10.1

Lattakia

17.8

14.9

6.2

0.6

0.1

8.3

Idleb

6.3

10.6

10.9

6.1

2.6

9.3

Aleppo

2.6

6.7

18.6

26.3

19.7

15.6

Al-Rakka

0.5

1.9

3.8

8.4

29.1

4.5

Deir-ez-Zor

9.2

9.4

6.2

4.1

3.2

6.8

Al-Hassakeh

0.4

1.1

7.9

26.8

22.4

9.6

Sweida

2.2

3.1

4.8

3.9

1.9

3.9

Dara'a

5.4

3.5

6.2

4.5

1.2

4.9

Quneitra

0.6

0.8

0.7

0.5

0.1

0.7

All Syria (%)

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

All Syria (Number)

49 185

155 586

238 346

118 426

11 650

573 193

Source: Computed from 1994 census of agriculture.

Table 11.7 exhibits the size distribution of landed holdings by type of tenure. It can be seen that the size distribution of holdings with not fully owned land is much more skewed towards the larger classes. This must reflect the importance of the farming entrepreneurs and other joint stock farming companies.

Table 11.7 Size distribution of landed holdings by types of tenure

Holding area size classes (ha)

Holders own all land

Holders rent all land

Holders by other types

Holders by more than one type

All holders

No. of Holders

%

No. of Holders

%

No. of Holders

%

No. of Holders

%

No. of Holders

%

<0.5

47 483

9.2

590

3.1

865

4.6

247

1.2

49 185

8.6

0.5-2

146 642

28.5

2 769

14.3

3 592

19.2

2 583

12.7

155 586

27.1

2-10

214 285

41.6

6 695

34.7

8 507

45.5

8 859

43.4

238 346

41.6

10-50

97 383

18.9

8 289

42.9

5 368

28.7

7 386

36.2

118 426

20.7

>50

8 959

1.7

967

5.0

381

2.0

1 343

6.6

11 650

2.0

Total

514 752

100.0

19 310

100.0

18 713

100.0

20 418

100.0

573 193

100.0

Source: Computed from 1994 census of agriculture.

11.3 Agricultural labour

Estimates of labour employed in agriculture are difficult in Syria for lack of appropriate consistent data. As reported officially in the Central Bureau of Statistics (CBS) 2001 Statistical Abstract, employment in agriculture and forestry was estimated at 1 430 000 in 2000 (of which 961 000 male, and 469 000 female), a 33 percent increase from 1994, representing 32 percent of total employment. However, the analysis in chapter one of this volume suggested that the total labour force employed in agriculture in 1999 was equal to only 828 000 people (704 000 male and 114 000 female). This amounts to only 17.6 percent of the estimated active labour force (Sarris, 2003), and compares with official figures of 1 081 000 in 1998 and 918 000 people in 1991, or 28.2 percent of the total employment then. The IMF in turn (IMF 2000b) estimated the employment in agriculture in 1998 at 1 233 000 (1 200 000 private and 33 000 public), which is about 14 percent higher than what is estimated above, and accounts for 29 percent of the total employment.

The share of total employed females working in agriculture is high relative to other sectors, and constitutes the bulk (58.8 percent) of female employment. By contrast, the share for males is only 26.2 percent. Women in Syria account for 33 percent of agricultural labour, and in particular represent a large share of seasonal agricultural workers, who in turn largely come from low-income households. The significant decline of agricultural employment in 1999 by 23.5 percent, which was mostly accounted for by declines in female agricultural employment, is interesting. As women in Syria account for a large share of seasonal agricultural workers, and largely come from low-income households, the large decline in that type of employment in 1999 suggests that the drought must have affected considerably those poor households that depend of agricultural wages for part of their income.

Out of the total number of people employed in agriculture in 1991, official estimates report that 361 000 were unpaid family workers (148 000 male, and 213 000 female), 145 000 were paid workers (84 000 male and 61 000 female), 280 000 were self employed (266 000 male and 14 000 female), and 132 000 were employers (126 000 male and 6 000 female). It is quite clear that the bulk of females working in agriculture in 1991 were unpaid family workers, and of the rest, the overwhelming share was paid workers. It is not clear or derivable from existing statistics, what the corresponding picture is now.

Another source of information on agricultural labour is the 1994 agricultural census, according to which (Table 11.8) the total number of family members employed in private agricultural holdings was 1.94 million. This number does not consider the fact that many family members are only partly employed in the family holding. The table indicates that the average number of family members per holding is relatively stable over different land size classes, at about 3.7.

Table 11.8 Labour utilized by farm holdings by size categories

Farm size classes (ha)

Number of holdings

Total family workers

Total area planted (ha)

Number of permanent workers

Number of full time equivalent temporary workers

Total number of full time hired workers

Family workers per holding

Family workers per ha

Total hired workers per holding

Total hired workers per ha

Landless

40 403

59 525

0

773

99

872

1.47


0.02


<0.5

48 405

107 308

13 699

1 719

449

2168

2.22

7.83

0.04

0.16

0.5-2

153 191

449 735

161 596

7 550

3 880

11430

2.94

2.78

0.07

0.07

2-10

233 669

862 360

989 771

17 725

16 192

33917

3.69

0.87

0.15

0.03

10-50

114 538

418 570

2 069 818

17 989

14 273

32262

3.65

0.20

0.28

0.02

>50

10 840

40 644

965 562

5 253

2 601

7854

3.75

0.04

0.72

0.01

All country

601 046

1 938 142

4 200 446

51 009

37 495

88 504

3.22

0.46

0.15

0.02

Source: Computed from the 1994 Agricultural census.

Hired workers (permanent workers, plus the full time equivalent of temporary workers, computed by dividing the number of days worked by all temporary workers by 250), account for only about 88 500 full time equivalent person-years, of which permanent workers constitute 58 percent. The reason is that, while there are 1.6 million temporary workers employed by all holders, the average number of days each temporary worker works is only 5.9. The amount of hired labour increases with the size of holding, as expected, but the amount of both family, as well as hired labour per ha of cultivated land decreases as farm size increases. This suggests that larger farms are more capital intensive than smaller ones, and that labour productivity is much higher on larger size farms.

Employment opportunities for full-time or occasional workers vary throughout the country and are affected by seasonality. In many parts of Syria, in the Hama countryside, as an example, a situation of labour shortage during harvesting co-exists with relative labour abundance throughout the year. The number of totally landless labourers in the Hama governorate is said not to exceed 10 percent but is constantly on the increase because of population growth, insufficient development of non-agricultural employment opportunities, and continuing fragmentation of holdings through inheritance. However, in view of the active labour demand during the peak agricultural seasons, open unemployment of agricultural labour exists mainly for about two months in the slack season only. A similar situation is true for Hassakeh, where in some cases a large part of seasonal labour for harvesting comes from other areas, and where farmers can have problems in finding hired labour during the peak season (Shahaideh et al., 2001). According to the same source, seasonal job opportunities are available for men both within and outside the relevant areas, but for women it would be often difficult to find seasonal work in other areas. A different picture is presented for Lattakia, an area of intensive small family farms, where family labour prevails, and off-farm job opportunities are scarce.

Landless labourer households, i.e. those households not operating land under any form and not having a non-agricultural employment, were recorded in Forni’s (2001) field survey as accounting for between 6 and 36 percent of total households in the eight surveyed villages. This means that this category has a varying significance across the territory. Furthermore, because they resort to pluriactivity, i.e. their participation to several sectors and not agriculture only, the landless as a category do not necessarily coincide with the poor households.

The landlessness situation in some parts of central Syria, e.g. Idleb, is serious as it is characterized by limited numbers of totally landless labourers, but an overwhelming presence of near-landless households. Eighty percent of the households cultivate less than one hectare of land and another 15 cultivate between one and three ha. This means that the minimum subsistence security provided by the land base is such that the social balance may be toppled with another round of subdivisions through inheritance. Furthermore, in a situation of this type, the prospective employers of agricultural labour force, namely those having a land base big enough to require labour in addition to household resources, are limited. This explains the presence of many organized labour groups in this Mohafaza, which bring to other areas the surplus labour of Idleb. There is fortunately some complementarity between the different labour peaks, i.e. Idleb’s labour migrates after the local peak demand and moves to work with other crops in other areas.

More generally, in Syria, agricultural labour organization and mobilization functions in accordance with local and non-local demand. Traditional labour contractors, the chawesh, perform these functions. They pool mainly female labour and make it available in different governorates according to market demand.

Another phenomenon relevant to labour use and its coordination is inter-household cooperation between farmers producing different crops and hence having different labour requirement peaks. For instance cotton-producing farmers get into cooperation with onion-producing farmers and exchange their family labour, as needed. However, a broader information system on labour supply and demand is missing.

The scarcity of land, coupled with insecurity of income creates a tendency among workers to occupy land permanently whenever possible. Labourers are said to want to become sharecroppers, who are more difficult to evict, while all employers would like to continue using casual unprotected labour. Currently, however, labourers with no own production base are unlikely to be able to become squatters, and hence slowly acquire rights to stay on the land. This is because labourers are employed for short periods only and for specific tasks only for the very purpose of preventing any possibility for them to settle on the land and claim any right to it.

In general, the increasing supply of labour is not matched by similar increase in demand and results in stagnation of daily wage rates. For instance, wage rates had actually slightly decreased in Al-Hassakeh in 2000 over 1999 for cotton picking, a relatively well-paid activity for female seasonal migrant labour.

It should, however, be noted that Syrian agricultural labour moves in a larger than national context. Findings from a field survey conducted in the Idleb and Hama Mohafazat in early 2001 indicate that workers compare the local daily rates with those prevailing in Lebanon or in the Gulf. In the case of Lebanon the rates would be about five times higher for comparable work, and the proximity allows labourers to move out easily. It is mainly women, more constrained by social custom, who are continuing to operate in the national market only, but by no means in the purely local one. Women constitute the bulk of the migrant labour force which the Chawesh mobilize to provide the needed number of labourers at the right place and time for all the major agricultural operations, and particularly harvest.


[82] The total area operated by the private holders of table 11.6 in 1994 according to the census was 4 687.5 000 ha, of which 4 609.2 000 ha was cultivable. This contrasts with the figure for total area held by agricultural holders, reported in the Annual Statistical Abstract of 1999, which can be calculated (by multiplying the number of holders by the average area) to be equal to 5 197.7 thousand ha, of which 5 105.6 thousand is cultivable. The Annual Statistical Abstract 1999 also reports that the total cultivable land in Syria is 5 981 thousand ha, of which 5 484 thousand is cultivated. Clearly, there are some major discrepancies between these data. For instance, the difference between the total cultivable land reported in the Statistical Abstract and the total cultivable land of census respondents is about 1 372 thousand ha, while the difference between the total cultivated land reported in the Statistical Abstract and the total land cultivated by census respondents (which is 4 525.3 thousand ha) is 960 thousand ha.

There is another form of arable land not reported in the census, mostly owned by the Government. According to 1984 data, a small proportion of public agricultural lands was cultivated by eight production cooperatives (about 3 000 ha). These were established by the Government through relocation of farmers displaced by the filling of lake Assad. In 2001, 12 state farms occupied another 112 420 ha, of which 70 977 ha were cultivable, and 50 588 ha were actually cultivated, and of these 19 904 were irrigated. Another 12 state farms occupied another 6 340 ha in 1993 and produced largely livestock products. Seven joint ventures with mixed private and public financing existed in year 2000, with a total of 7 242 ha. Apart from the private landowners, cooperatives, and state farms, there are another 39.4 thousand ha currently utilised by GOEDEB of which 24.8 thousand ha are cultivable. The total area of the above classes, that are most likely not included in the census, amounts to 168 thousand ha, of which about 85 thousand ha are cultivable. This still leaves a large gap between reported official total cultivable and cultivated area, and land operated by various types of holders. The discrepancy suggests that there is a considerable amount of land that is public land, and which is farmed under some type of unspecified tenure (squatters,etc), or that the number of those who have leased public land is much larger than what was reported above.

To some extent the discrepancy might be accounted for by the distribution of expropriated lands. According to the 1993 Annual Statistical Abstract, by 1975 there were 1 401.3 thousand ha that had been expropriated, of which 351.4 thousand were not distributed, 254 thousand ha were allocated to cooperatives, ministries and other organisations, 329.8 thousand was excluded and sold land, and 466.1 thousand were distributed lands. If it is assumed that the distributed lands are included in the holdings of the 1994 agricultural census, and that half of the land allocated to co-operatives, ministries and organisations is not included in the census, then the above figures result in about 808 thousand ha that are public land, and have either been distributed to organisations, ministries, etc, or have been not distributed. This is a figure that comes close to bridging the gap between the reported figures in the census and the Statistical Abstract. Since this land represents about 14 percent of the total cultivable land in Syria, it is interesting to inquire as to the current uses of this land. If, as is reported informally, there are many squatters who utilise public land for private cultivation without any formal arrangement, then it would be important to find out how many there are, how much land they cultivate and what they produce, if they benefit from any public policies, such as subsidised inputs and credit, and what types of income sources they have. This suggests that the issue of land tenure might still be a very live one, despite years of land reform.


Previous Page Top of Page Next Page