ACCÈS À LA TERRE, AU CAPITAL ET AUX REVENUS NON AGRICOLES DANS UNE PERSPECTIVE DE RÉDUCTION DE LA PAUVRETÉ EN MILIEU RURAL

Le cadre actuel de la croissance économique et du développement inclut une tendance générale vers la privatisation des droits fonciers, l'effondrement des structures collectives en agriculture, ainsi qu'une dépendance des marchés fonciers comme moyen pour les agriculteurs de participer au processus de développement. Malgré la disparition de la réforme foncière de l'ordre du jour politique, il est clair que les situations qui ont conduit dans le passé à la mise en place de réformes foncières n'ont pas disparu. Cet article discute la pertinence de prendre en compte les structures foncières dans le cadre de l'évaluation des politiques macroéconomiques qui ont une incidence sur l'agriculture. Sont également abordés: les liens entre la sécurité de la tenure foncière et l'accès au revenu et aux ressources; la nature et la performance du marché foncier en ce qui concerne la participation des populations rurales pauvres; et finalement le lien entre les structures agraires et le revenu non agricole. La conclusion tirée est que la réduction de la pauvreté rurale requiert des actions à facettes multiples, qui reconnaissent les liens entre les possibilités d'accès aux ressources des ménages, les stratégies de revenu des ménages et les changements macroéconomiques et structurels.

ACCESO A LA TIERRA, OBTENCIÓN DE INGRESOS EXTRAPREDIALES Y ACCESO AL CAPITAL EN RELACIÓN CON LA REDUCCIÓN DE LA POBREZA RURAL

El actual marco de crecimiento económico y desarrollo incluye una tendencia general hacia la privatización de los derechos sobre la tierra y el colapso de las estructuras colectivas en la agricultura, así como una perspectiva hacia los mercados como vías para que los campesinos accedan a participar en el proceso de desarrollo. No obstante la eliminación de la reforma agraria como parte explícita de la agenda política, es claro que las situaciones que llevaron a la activación de las reformas del régimen de tenencia de tierras en décadas pasadas no han desaparecido. Este artículo analiza la relevancia del análisis de los sistemas de tenencia de la tierra cuando se evalúan políticas macroeconómicas que afectan a la agricultura. También se discuten los vínculos entre seguridad en la tenencia de la tierra y acceso a ingresos y otros activos; la naturaleza y el desempeño de los mercados de tierra en relación con la participación de los pobres rurales y, finalmente, la relación entre estructuras organizacionales agrarias e ingresos extraprediales. Se concluye que la reducción de la pobreza rural requiere esfuerzos de políticas múltiples, que reconozcan los vínculos existentes entre las opciones de acceso a activos por parte de las unidades domésticas, las estrategias de ingreso que realizan esas unidades, y los cambios macroestructurales.

Land access, off-farm income and capital access in relation to the reduction of rural poverty

Jolyne Melmed-Sanjak
Susana Lastarria-Cornhiel

The current framework of economic growth and development includes a general trend towards the privatization of land rights and a collapse of collective structures in agriculture as well as a move towards reliance on land markets as the means of peasant access to participation in the development process. Despite the removal of land reform as an explicit part of the policy agenda, it is clear that the situations which led to the activation of land reforms in past decades are still in place. This article discusses the relevance of looking at land tenure systems when evaluating macroeconomic policies that affect agriculture. Also discussed are the link between land tenure security and access to income and assets; the nature and performance of land markets with regard to the participation of the rural poor; and the link between agrarian organizational structures and off-farm income. The conclusion reached is that rural poverty reduction requires multifaceted policy efforts that recognize the linkages among household asset access portfolios, household income strategies and macrostructural changes.

INTRODUCTION

Understanding the linkages between access to land (size and ownership structures) and access to other sources of income and capital is an essential element in the policy dialogue about food security and poverty reduction. The current framework of economic growth and development includes a general trend towards the privatization of land rights and a collapse of collective structures in agriculture as well as a move towards reliance on land markets as the means of peasant access to participation in the development process. Despite the removal of land reform as an explicit part of the policy agenda, it is clear that the situations which led to the activation of land reforms in past decades are still in place. It is still very important, therefore, for these issues to be addressed, albeit following a "market-oriented" approach (Shearer, Lastarria-Cornhiel and Mesbah, 1991).
There is ample evidence of continued pervasive rural poverty and hunger, starting at little changed and low-productivity agrarian structures. The underutilization of land resources by some and the intensive, degrading use of marginal lands by multitudes of land-poor peasant farmers still characterize contemporary agrarian structures (Kay, 1994; de Janvry and Sadoulet, 1989a; Thiesenhusen and Melmed-Sanjak, 1990; Thiesenhusen, 1991; Salgado, 1994; Melmed-Sanjak, 1992; Binswanger and Elgin, 1990; Lopez and Romano, 1995). Thus, de Janvry and Sadoulet (1989a) say "the leading cause of rural poverty is the lack of sufficient access to land and low-productivity of land".
Yet, implicit in the policy regimes of market liberalization (structural adjustment) is the fact that there is no need for action other than removing government-imposed constraints on the operation of markets because - as it is said - when markets are allowed to work, growth will occur and all will benefit. Several authors have questioned the exclusionary/inclusionary nature of contemporary macroeconomic growth strategies (Kay, 1994; Carter and Mesbah, 1993; Stonich, 1992; de Janvry, Sadoulet and Davis, 1995; Melmed-Sanjak, 1992) when discussing directly the implications for food security. A fair conclusion that receives much support in the empirical literature is that, while the modus of land reform in the past needed to be structurally adjusted, today's structural adjustment policies need to encompass some forms of land reform (e.g. land market development policies that explicitly address the ability of the poor rural strata to participate as well as issues of land tenure insecurity). In particular, two key differences in present-day land policy are:

  1. the use of market-oriented strategies; and
  2. recognition of the interlinkages among land markets and other rural factor (e.g. capital and labour) markets.

Furthermore, concern about problems of environmental degradation and long-term survival increasingly focuses on problems of peasants' access to and use of land resources (Thiesenhusen, 1991). In this vein, Reardon and Vosti (1995) offer a "new conceptual framework to explore the poverty-environment links" asserting that "the range of types of poverty is the range of lack of various assets (and income flows derived from them ...)". Their call for the application of household economics and for the analysis of income strategies to be "brought to bear on understanding the environment-poverty links" is already being pursued and increasingly recognized (Larson and Bromley, 1990; Perrings, 1989).
In the light of the above, to rationalize the persistence of rural poverty and hunger, the entitlements failure approach proposed by Sen (1981) for explaining famine seems very relevant. Sen's approach strongly suggests that food supply is not a problem of hunger but rather that hunger is a problem of access to the available supply as determined by entitlements. Entitlements vary across groups within social systems and across social systems. It is clear to us that around the rural areas of the globe, access to food is determined at least partly by a person's access to various types of capital (e.g. land, physical non-land, human and financial).
Thus, Sen's approach points out the usefulness of the current conceptual frameworks for classifying groups according to asset typologies that are being presented in discussions on various aspects of rural poverty (de Janvry, Sadoulet, and Davis, 1995; Reardon and Vosti, 1995; Carter and Kalfayan, 1989). Of particular importance is the issue of how agrarian structure (landownership structures and farm-size distributions) is or is not a key to defining these typologies. This is a primary focus of the present article, in which evidence is presented in favour of an approach to food security that promotes off-farm income generation and land access enhancement as complementary parts of a policy regime.
This conclusion is reached through a synopsis of various strands of relevant literature. First, there is a general discussion of the relevance of looking at land tenure systems when evaluating macroeconomic policies that affect agriculture. This is followed by a more detailed discussion of the link between land tenure security and access to income and assets, the nature and performance of land markets with regard to the participation of the rural poor and, finally, the link between agrarian structures and off-farm income. In the concluding section, these three pieces are brought together in a macropicture and brief discussion of policy.

REVIEW OF EMPIRICAL LITERATURE

Agrarian structure, access to capital and the implications of agricultural sector policy for the rural poor
As mentioned in the introduction, there is discordance between contemporary macropolicy initiatives and the microfoundations through which they operate. A key conclusion from analysing the impacts of macropolicy through the lens of microeconomic decision-making models is that access to various forms of capital is pivotal in determining household income strategies and, therefore, in determining the likely change in household behaviours and well-being when faced with macropolicy changes. Mention of two such modelling exercises, which also offer empirical insights, should suffice to demonstrate this important revelation.
First, Carter and Mesbah (1993) conduct a simulation analysis of how various strata of the Chilean peasantry will fare in the land market during a period of rapid agricultural export-led growth. Their exercise is based on the theoretical model of household behavioural strategies developed in Carter and Kalfayan (1989). A key factor in this model, and hence in defining the differentiated behaviours of various classes of rural households, is that households are stratified according to resource endowments (or asset typologies) which imply different behavioural strategies. Each stratum is differently constrained by its relative need for and ability to participate in size-sensitive rural factor markets. A typology of rural households is defined, including proletarian, semi-proletarian, peasant and capitalist family farms and hierarchical capitalist farms. These farms differ in particular in their capacity to increase access to landholdings and financial capital and decrease reliance on off-farm employment for survival. The latter three forms of farming differ significantly also with regard to the types of labour employed on their farms. The implications of this typology for participation in the land market are striking and are discussed under Land markets as a means of access for the rural poor, p. 60.
Put simply, these authors amply demonstrate a problem with policy models which, as de Janvry, Sadoulet and Davis (1995) say, "... generally abstract from these features [market failures, transactions costs, etc.] and postulate instead the existence of perfect markets with exceptions such as surplus labour, price regulation ...". The authors make this statement in the context of showing how consideration of microeconomic features, such as whether or not a household is a net buyer or net seller of a farm commodity, matters for the distribution of the benefits and costs of the North American Free Trade Agreement [NAFTA]. (Similar results were demonstrated by de Janvry and Sadoulet (1989b) in the context of Ecuador.) Their conceptual framework relies on a typology of rural households which stresses "differential income strategies based on access to land per adult member ...". Their typology focused on how different forms of capital determine earnings level.
Carter and Weibe (1990) look at the "evolution of landownership structure itself". Their model and data postulate that working capital constraints (ex ante capital) combined with consumption credit constraints (ex post capital) lead the poor to the adoption of safety-first strategies entailing the growing of basic foods (food security). This is a consequence of size-sensitive access to capital. Thus, smallholders systematically opt away from high-profit commercial crop production which then stifles their ability to accumulate land over time. Larger farms, which do not face such constraints on capital, are thus advantaged in short-term income distribution and in long-term capacity of land accumulation via the market.
Within a similar framework, Carter (1994) reviews the issues of class basis and bias of agrarian growth in Paraguay. He demonstrates again the short-term effects on small farm participation and net employment effects which take place given a static distribution of land. More important, he draws attention to how resulting differences in economic returns across variously sized farms might cause a structural change in the ownership distribution of land via the operation of imperfect land markets that favour medium-sized to big farms. Furthermore, caution Reardon and Vosti (1995), "... in the long run, if a household is investment-poor [asset-constrained] but not welfare-poor [absolute income standard], it may lead to natural resource degradation that eventually causes the household to become welfare-poor ...".
In summary, it can be said that asset typologies define rural classes according to asset portfolios which tend to stratify according to farm size groups. Therefore, different farm size groups will be observed to use different behavioural strategies (income strategies). These differences will affect the outcomes of macroeconomic policy decisions and, hence, must be recognized and taken into consideration at the point of policy design.

Land titling tenure security and investment in agriculture
Increasing attention has been given since the early 1980s to land titling as a means of increasing tenure security. The titling of land (and the registration of titles in a public registry) is considered to be the best way to protect ownership rights to land, in other words, the best form of tenure security. Land titling and registration is the highest level of formalization of ownership rights in private property tenure systems. Where private property as a tenure form is not dominant, however, land titling has little consequence or utility because land- holders acquire tenure security through other mechanisms (e.g. membership in a group or family). This explains why titling programmes in some areas either have little impact, unintended effects, or quickly become outdated (for example, title documents are not kept up to date when property is transferred). It also explains the low participation rates in some supply-driven titling efforts, e.g. Honduras.
Greater tenure security, theoretically, has two impacts: increased agricultural productivity and more dynamic land markets. Titling is expected to facilitate land transfers, stimulate the land market and increase the supply of land on the market; thus, it can be a mechanism for redistributing land and making land more accessible to landless and land-poor farmers. Feder et al. (1988) argued that land titles reduce the uncertainty over the entitlement of owners to maintain or transfer land rights and, in turn, affect the price and scope of land transactions. They hypothesize that greater security of ownership raises farm productivity and, as a result, the market value of land is higher for titled land than for an identical parcel that is not titled. The most commonly recognized benefit from the titling and registration of land, besides the tenure security bestowed on the property owner, is the use of those secure ownership rights as collateral to solicit credit. Formal lending agencies, such as banks, often require not only that property being used as collateral be titled, but that the title be registered. In fact, the rationalization for the cost of titling and registration programmes is that they put capital into the hands of people with little wealth and a low income, leading to increased investment and productivity by these families.
Titling and/or registration of ownership rights to land, it has been argued, increases the productivity of land because:

  1. increased tenure security provides incentives to invest time, labour and capital in the land (making improvements) and agricultural production (buying inputs);
  2. titled land can be used as collateral to secure credit (capital) for investment, thus making credit more abundant; and
  3. titling facilitates land transfers, resulting in land moving into the hands of more productive farmers.

The impact of titling and tenure security on credit availability and agricultural productivity can be broken down into supply and demand effects. Demand effects occur when the acquisition of a land title increases the farmer's security and certainty that he or she will be able to maintain possession of the land and benefit from investments that improve its productive capacity. Increased security is hypothesized to enhance investment incentives and increase the demand for capital and variable inputs complementary to capital and, thereby, raise agricultural productivity. Supply effects result when the provision of a secure and legal land title improves a farmer's access to cheaper and longer-term institutional credit because the land can be pledged as collateral for loans. Output on securely owned (i.e. titled) parcels is consequently expected to be greater than on untitled parcels because of a greater use of inputs of capital and other variable production factors and potential shifts to more capital-intensive corps. Thus, the combined demand and supply effects, it is hypothesized, cause higher farm productivity on titled land and also raise the price that titled land can command in the land market.
The rationale provided by Feder et al. (1988) for land titling, however, ignores a number of other factors which shape farm productivity and may affect the desired outcomes of titling programmes. Stanfield (1985) argues that, in addition to ownership security, farmers' investment decisions are affected by a number of factors such as alternative investment opportunities, accessibility of production inputs, the farmer's present debt structure and overall profitability of farming and the availability of investment capital. These factors are dependent on agricultural and macroeconomic policies. Moreover, the assumption that credit is available must be seriously questioned. In an environment of imperfect capital markets, small farmers' access to credit is rationed and a title to land may not overcome the obstacles to obtaining access to institutional credit.
Further, under some conditions, the provision of land titles may work to the disadvantage of smallholders. As Carter (1994) points out: "If titled land operates as collateral ... then foreclosure and land loss is a real possibility. The threat of land loss is of course supposed to mitigate moral hazard problems associated with credit contracts. But in a stochastic agricultural environment which lacks insurance markets, the farmer faces a genuine erogenous probability of loss of titled and mortgaged parcels."
Under these circumstances, the impact of land titles on individual investment incentives and productivity is likely to be greater for wealthier farmers whose land size and wealth (access to other assets) leave them favourably situated with respect to capital and insurance markets. For smallholder farmers, potential benefits of land titles may be overwhelmed by market access problems, leaving little incentive for title acquisition.
While definitive and conclusive studies on the long-term effects of land titling on the agrarian structure still need to be undertaken, assessments and studies undertaken in the last decade seem to indicate that titling, in and of itself, does not increase credit transactions, improve production levels on titled land or increase the number of land transactions (Seligson and Nesman, 1989; Boster et al., 1989; Stanfield et al., 1986; Larson, 1995). A preliminary report by Lopez and Romano (1995) indicates some positive differences in investment and credit for titled farmers over non-titled farmers. However, this study examines the same sample of farmers from Honduras that Larson (1995) uses in her analysis. Lopez and Romano's data were collected one year later and include an additional sample from another region in Honduras. The fact that their results are inconsistent means that more attention is needed in evaluating their data as well as their competing methodologies and the differences between the two regions in Honduras. Finally, despite a lack of evidence of productivity effects, there is evidence of a significant impact of titling on the market price of land (Salgado, 1994; Larson, 1995; Carter, Luz and Galeano, 1992). This could reflect the capitalized value of the costs of acquiring a land title as well as perceived implications of title for tenure security and access to credit. Such perceptions are witnessed by Larson (1995).
An assessment of titling programmes in Latin America (Stanfield, 1990) reached the following conclusions:

Studies of titling and registration programmes in Africa appear to arrive at similar and even stronger conclusions. Atwood (1990), in his comprehensive article on the formalization of land rights in Africa, cautioned against assuming positive results from land titling. Atwood reviewed three claims attributed to land titling: increased productivity through improved factor mobility (land transfers), increased access to agricultural credit and increased on-farm investment. He found that results of titling in Africa are mixed at best. The same conclusion is reached by Gavian and Fafchamps (1996).
First of all, land registration may reduce risks and transaction costs for some landowners but, for certain large sectors, particularly small landholders who formerly depended on customary tenure mechanisms, risk and transaction costs actually increase. For example, in Kenya transaction costs are sufficiently high to discourage registration of land transfers. And, as mentioned before, titled land may have a higher risk of being lost than customarily held land. Second, with regard to credit access, financial markets in Africa are generally not available for small farmers, even if they hold titled land. This is mainly because transaction costs for small farmers are prohibitively high and because bank credit going to agriculture is determined by factors other than profitability. In other words, the credit for agriculture is not available in any case. In addition, land as collateral is not that attractive or useful in Africa since, because of cultural norms and administrative problems, financial institutions are loath to foreclose on landed property.
Finally, Atwood found that substantial investments in land improvements and in new technology have taken place in Africa, whether ownership has been formalized or not. Most African farmers are secure in their holdings at present, and their decision to invest and increase productivity is based on other factors, suggesting that indigenous tenure systems, in spite of offering limited individualized land rights, have not had a negative impact on agricultural productivity. Larson and Bromley (1990) reach a similar conclusion about the role of private versus communal ownership forms in promoting environmental conservation.
Barrows and Roth (1989), after reviewing evidence from numerous regions in Africa, conclude that land registration has had very little effect on investment demand. It appears that, while titles increase lenders' security, financial markets in Africa have not substantially increased the credit supply. Thus, a title to land appears to be less important in determining farm productivity than other factors such as market (capital and factor) access.
In addition, the formalization of ownership rights is not unbiased. Titling seems to be self-selective in that landowners who already have tenure security are more likely to seek a title (Carter, Weibe and Blarel, 1991). These owners tend to have larger landholdings, be better educated and grow cash crops. Some studies have also found that titling programmes are often utilized by people who, because of their position, education or personal contacts, are able to acquire a title to land that actually belongs to someone else.

Land markets as a means of access for the rural poor
In the past, arguments for progressive land reforms were often supported with both equity and productivity arguments. The widely accepted observation of an inverse relationship between farm size and output per unit of land was a basis for the productivity argument. In the current environment of reliance on private property and market allocations, the inverse relationship yields the expectation that competitive land markets would reallocate land towards the smaller end of the agrarian structure. The next sections briefly review the evidence on the inverse relationship and then focus on research efforts that demonstrate the limitations to the assumption that land markets, as currently constituted, will generate redistributive outcomes.

The inverse farm size-productivity relationship. A comprehensive review of the literature that provides worldwide evidence of an inverse farm size-productivity relationship, as related to the rationale for land redistribution, is found in Domer (1992). The basic explanation is found in differences in resource endowments which lead small farms to allocate more labour per unit of land, thus cultivating the land more intensively than larger farms. Kevane (1996) reviews the literature, including the works of Carter and Weibe (1990), Eswaran and Kotwal (1986) and Feder (1985), which sugges that the nature of markets provides incentives for large farms to cultivate extensively and small farms to cultivate intensively, causing land redistribution being viewed as a win-win process of efficiency and equity.
More recent papers that address the relationship between farm size, resource allocation and productivity in the context of size-sensitive markets provide some evidence of innuendoes which suggest a competitiveness gap for small farms in contrast to a strictly inverse relationship. Carter and Weibe (1990), for example, report on farm data from Kenya which indicate a U-shaped relationship (which is at first inverse but quickly becomes positive). This pattern, they argue, is explained easily using the Carter-Kalfayan theory of farm size-rationed access to working capital, which favours larger farms combined with imperfect labour markets that facilitate small farm family activities based on an intensive use of family labour. The labour advantage of the very small landholder is eventually overridden by capital constraints.
Kevane (1996) provides another example. He argues that earlier discussions of the inverse relationship overlook the roles of wealth and the ability to bear risk in determining behavioural strategies. His analysis is of data from the Sudan, where land is not the main constraint. Similar to Carter and Kalfayan (1989), Kevane builds a decision model of optimal labour-land ratios under different "regimes of market imperfections", and this confirms the explanations given above. This model shows three regimes under which the relationship between farm size and land productivity becomes positive. These are empirically supported with data from the western Sudan.

The nature of land markets: structure and function. In view of the discussion of the discordance between the assumptions often implicit in macropolicy initiatives and household-level decisions, the first question to address is: "Are land markets perfect, competitive markets?" Various authors delineate the conditions for a land market to be characterized as competitive (Salgado, 1994; Munoz, 1993; Carter and Mesbah, 1993): homogeneity of the good (i.e. consistent quality and measure of each unit); freedom of entry (i.e. entry is not exclusive as a result of high transaction costs or institutionalized constraints such as laws preventing purchase beyond a certain size); a large number of agents; and uniform access to information. All of the authors cited assess extant land markets in various Latin American countries and clearly conclude that land markets are imperfect.
Markets tend to be very local and informal (in terms of documentation of transactions and property rights and of information dissemination). Land is obviously not a homogeneous commodity and in many places its quality varies even within microregions. Transaction costs are often very high, creating barriers to entry by the poor and disincentives for participation on the part of holders of large tracts of land. In many circumstances, until recently, government rules restricted or even prohibited various forms of land transactions. In these circumstances, much informal activity continued but it was largely unrecorded and often only use rights were transacted. Finally, informality results in very uneven access to information. Availability of land is often announced only through kinship and friendship networks, for example.
Other authors (Land Tenure Center, 1996; Wunderlich, 1995; Csaba, 1995) note that, in Eastern Europe, imperfections are such that land markets have not existed and therefore need to be developed. This must occur amid confusion over allocation rules for the privatization of state farms and a fear of further proliferation of tiny, fragmented farms. Given that access to capital is also possible in markets that are far from being competitive and developed and where the institutions that allow for markets to function competitively (e.g. registry systems) are not sufficiently established, it is fair to say that the lessons from the Latin American context are relevant.

What kind of participation and access do land markets offer the rural poor? First, it is important to mention that, even if land markets were competitive, it is unlikely that land would shift to the landless or land-poor. Binswanger (cited in Carter and Mesbah, 1993) identifies the "fundamental financing problem of the poor" as the culprit. The basic argument is that, in order to finance a land purchase in competitive capital markets, the poor would have to dig into current consumption, which they cannot afford to do.
If the existence of biases in access to finance is added to the list of land market imperfections, a situation of severely segmented land markets emerges. In this case, segmentation means that there are systematic forces that limit the fluidity of land transfers from the large-farm strata to the small-farm strata. Segmentation is also reflected in the fact that land price per unit is systematically and significantly higher for small parcels than for large parcels. Most sales occur between farms of similar sizes and, hence, a "barrier to accumulation" can be observed (Carter and Mesbah, 1993; Salgado, 1994).
Carter and Mesbah (1993) illustrate more specifically the relationship between agrarian structure, access to capital and the dynamics of land markets. First, the notion of landholding as a poverty refuge is borne out in their theory of land market dynamics; the smallest will express very high reservation prices and hold on to land. Second, slightly bigger semi-proletarian farms are capital-constrained and therefore unable to bid for land; they are more likely to shrink to "poverty refuge" size. Third, the "capitalized family farm" - a label introduced by Lehmann (1982) to refer to a medium-sized farm that maintains the family labour advantages of peasant farm units yet is able to acquire capital and compete in markets with commercial farm units - is in a strongly competitive position to buy land. It is between these latter two categories that a "barrier to accumulation is observed" in their simulation analysis. It is important to note that these results are not defined by productivity differentials but rather stem strictly from a person's position in the agrarian structure and the according biases in rural factor markets.
Segmentation thus results from both the demand side (constrained access to long-term and working capital) and the supply side (transaction costs and informational constraints to making small parcel sizes available on the market). Salgado (1994), Larson (1995), PRODEPAH (1994), Domer and Saliba (1981), Carter (1994) and Carter, Luz and Galeano (1992) provide ample documentation of such segmentation of land markets.
Given that the main topic of this article is the role of land policy in current food security policy, it is useful to mention several papers that address land market dynamics and access of rural poor in the context of agricultural export-led growth. Carter and Mesbah (1993) ask whether land market reform will lead to more inclusionary growth than prior bouts of growth based on agricultural exports. Unfortunately, they conclude that action is necessary in both land market and rural capital market reform if inclusionary growth is desired. Carter, Luz and Galeano (1992) show that, in Paraguay's agro-export zones where land is relatively scarce, growth is exclusionary - the extant land market does not provide access for the rural poor. On the other hand, in the land-abundant frontier zone, smallholders do have expansion possibilities via land accumulation. However, these zones are also likely to be environmentally sensitive areas.
Childress (1995) similarly shows that "In El Salvador, a macroeconomic pattern of spending fuelled by a foreign exchange boom ... is closing off the land purchase market to small farmers." Perhaps most interesting is the evaluation by Barhan, Carter and Sigelko (1995) of small farmers' participation in the production of non-traditional agricultural export crops in Guatemala. They address two questions: who adopts such crops and what are the consequences for the evolution of agrarian structure via land markets? They conclude that adoption is positively linked to farm size (because of scale effects in production and scale bias in credit access and risk), although all but the tiniest farms are likely to allocate some land to non-traditional crops, unlike earlier export periods. This difference is attributed to the labour-intensive nature of the kinds of vegetable (broccoli and snow peas) being grown. However, these small-farm adopters are shown to face an "adoption ceiling" owing to credit constraints.
With regard to the land market participation question, Barhan, Carter and Sigelko (1995) show that the adopters do have better, albeit still limited, accumulation possibilities while non-adopters find that their traditional "life cycle" patterns are interrupted.
Finally, the works of Domer and Saliba (1981), Carter (1994), Carter and Mesbah (1993), Carter, Luz and Galeano (1992) and PRODEPAH (1994) call attention to appropriate policy design to allow land markets to work better, i.e. have more of an impact on increasing agricultural productivity and alleviating rural poverty. Land taxation, mortgage banks and land banks as well as land titling and registration efforts are evaluated as means of land market reform. Land banks are likely to have the biggest impact for the rural poor. However, they note the very modest success of some early attempts to establish land banks in the context of least-developed countries, for example the Penny Foundation in Guatemala and the programmes of the United States Agency for International Development in Honduras.
PRODEPAH argues that these programmes have had limited success, primarily owing to their design. These design problems include: not addressing the lack of land available for supply; not recognizing the important role of access to short-term working capital; being too reliant on donor funds and bureaucratic administration rather than being constituted as for-profit, regulated institutions; failing to address issues of land titling and registration simultaneously; and limited committal of funds. All of these reports consider land market development policy as a needed tool but stress the need for a combined package of policy initiatives tailored to the specific nature of markets and institutions in a locality.

Off-farm income, agrarian structure and the dynamics of accumulation
0ff-farm income and agrarian structure. While there is much reference in the literature to off-farm income and the size distribution of farms, this relationship has not been a focus of much systematic analysis. It usually forms part of a broader focus on characterizing agrarian systems or structures. Even more absent from the literature is analysis that systematically explores the relationship between off-farm income and patterns of ownership (tenure) and accumulation. Therefore, this section of the article draws together bits and pieces of evidence about these relationships and their relevance in the context of the policy dialogue of rural poverty reduction.
Stamoulis (1996) notes two forces leading farm families to engage in off-farm employment activities: push factors (risk and land shortage) and pull factors (increased opportunity). The former would suggest a negative relationship of off-farm earnings to farm size while the latter might suggest a positive relationship. Stamoulis observes that empirical evidence has been found to support both. The bulk of the literature, however, has focused on push factors and off-farm income being a necessary part of the survival strategy of poor, land-constrained farm families. This is particularly characteristic of the theoretical literature which follows structuralist and Marxian perspectives to analyse the transformation of peasantries in the advent of modern economic growth (capitalism).
Reviews of the literature on the transformation of peasant populations are found in Kay (1994), Carter and Mesbah (1993), Hanson (1996), Stonich (1991), Barhan, Carter and Sigelko (1995) and de Janvry (1981). These authors point to a persistence and proliferation of a peasantry which is transformed into a mass of subfamily-sized farms dependent on wage labour for subsistence. A smaller group of peasant farmers are able to move up the agrarian structure towards commercial enterprise stature (Lehmann, 1982). Some of the authors focus strictly on the dynamics of rural factor markets as an explanation for the proliferation and persistence of a rural land-poor class. Others, most notably de Janvry (1981), merge this picture with the dynamics of industrial development, noting that it is in the interest of cheap wages and foods to maintain such a wage-dependent peasantry.
Hanson (1996) provides a very comprehensive review of the empirical literature on part-time farming. His review encompasses research on the United States, Europe and Latin America and points out how approaches to the issue of part-time farming and the conclusions reached differ across these regions. In the United States, the evidence shows no systematic relationship between farm size and the amount of off-farm income earned. In the European and Latin American contexts, on the other hand, historical patterns of landholding (e.g. feudalism and systems of partial inheritance) have created a context in which the need for off-farm income to supplement consumption is a basic characteristic of a vast number of households who access only very small farms. Not surprisingly, the incidence of part-time farming is strongly correlated with historical developments of a particular area; for example, some authors showed that, in areas without systems of partial inheritance, there is much less part-time farming.
Various other authors also demonstrate an inverse relationship between reliance on off-farm income and farm size (Reardon and Vosti, 1995; Lopez and Whittington, 1996; Stonich, 1991; de Janvry, Sadoulet and Davis, 1995; de Janvry and Sadoulet, 1989b; Domer 1992). These authors suggest that the importance of off-farm income varies by location and relative isolation (supply of jobs and land). Stonich (1991) also asks whether tenure matters (ownership versus rental) and finds that, in one study community in Honduras, there is no particular relationship while, in another, renters are more likely to migrate for earnings.

The use of off-farm income for investment and accumulation. It seems then that off-farm income can be viewed as positive in the sense of allowing a reprieve of destitution (consumption smoothing) but that this positive view is limited by the fact that it offers little in the way of accumulation and upward mobility. A more positive view of off-farm income-based strategies for poverty alleviation could be garnered by evidence that the rural poor use off-farm earnings for investment and accumulation of land and/or non-land assets which would lead them out of poverty. Unfortunately, the evidence about such behavioural links between earnings and investment is extremely scant. Following is a list of pieces of evidence that we were able to find:

These authors offer some positive evidence. However, it is important to recall that access to off-farm earnings themselves is quite varied with location as are opportunities to participate in investments. For example, informal discussions about the problem of land access in Honduras and El Salvador revealed to that, in El Salvador, most families have some link to migrant sources of income (remittances) and that this allows many at least to put a down payment for a loan for the purchase of land. In Honduras, however, several survey regions indicated a high degree of isolation from migrant income streams and a notable lack of ability to finance even down payments for land purchase. In these communities, those who bought land did so with earnings achieved in fortuitous years of high crop profitability or by selling some livestock. With regard to access to opportunities to invest, Reardon and Vosti (1995) astutely note that "where markets are absent or underdeveloped, or where there are constraints to market access (tied to resource endowments), one asset market or holding can be isolated from another".
For example, one cannot necessarily use earnings to buy land if supply-side bottlenecks are present. Clearly, it is imperative to generate more and better evidence which presents systematically the relationship between off-farm income, farm size and access to other assets.

THE MEANS TO IMPROVING ACCESS FOR THE RURAL POOR

It is clear that rural poverty reduction requires multifaceted policy efforts that recognize the linkages among household asset access portfolios, household income strategies and macrostructural changes. In particular, initiatives to promote access to off-farm earning opportunities together with reforms aimed at promoting access to land via the land market are called for. In our own observation, in the context of Central America and also of Eastern Europe, the scenarios are such that it will be nearly impossible for enough jobs to be created or for each small farmer to gain access to adequate amounts of land. In Honduras, for example, there are more than 150 000 landless poor and approximately 90 percent of the farm population holds less than 1 ha of land. Much of the remaining land is underutilized by extensive cattle ranching and speculative landholders. At the same time, the maquiladora industry has been an attractive source of wage increase for many rural persons, but its potential for creating so many jobs has been questioned, as has the unstable and limited income from it.
Speaking more generally of Latin America, authors such as Kay (1994) and de Janvry and Sadoulet (1989a) note the proliferation of very small farms with a falling average farm size and the lack of ability of employment opportunities to meet the needs of this growing population. Stonich (1992) similarly states: "The emergent semi-proletarianized peasantry had neither access to sufficient land nor to employment opportunities to reduce poverty." In reference to those who disfavour active land policy, Domer (1992) says: "In other words, there is an implicit notion that there are easier, less controversial and quicker ways to benefit the rural poor ... people cannot simply be `placed on hold' until they are needed by industry."
Stamoulis (1996) and other authors suggest that using off-farm income for investment in agriculture may induce productivity and agricultural employment effects, thereby generating a "virtuous circle" which can be "important for long-term food security and alleviation of rural poverty". We agree but argue that, for such a virtuous circle to function, it is necessary to develop rural land and credit markets to facilitate better access to land and non-land capital, at least for those small farmers who are poised to participate. If "anti-peasant" biases in policy and in the functioning of key rural markets are removed, there is a group of small farmers that could be highly competitive and productive - as is shown by a number of authors such as de Janvry and Sadoulet (1989a), Carter and Mesbah (1993), Barhan, Carter and Sigelko (1995) and Lehmann (1982). Thus, a virtuous circle might be set in action.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Atwood, D.A. 1990. Land registration in Africa: the impact on agricultural production. World Dev., 18(5): 659-671.

Barhan, B., Carter, M.R. & Sigelko, W. 1995. Agro-export production and peasant land access. Examining the dynamic between adoption and accumulation. J. Dev. Econ., 46: 85-107.

Barrows, R. & Roth, M. 1989. Land tenure and investment in African agriculture: theory and evidence. LTC Paper No. 136. Madison, WI, USA, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin.

Binswanger, H.P. & Elgin, M. 1990. Reflections on land reform and farm size. In C.K. Eicher & J.M. Staatz, eds. Agricultural development in the Third World. Baltimore, MA, USA, The Johns Hopkins University Press.

Boster, J., Seligson, M., Terrell, K. & Zevallos, J.V. 1989. Land tenure security in Ecuador: a preliminary study of Cayambe and Pedro Moncayo. Pittsburgh, PA, USA, Center for Latin American Studies, University of Pittsburgh. (manuscript)

Carter, M. 1994. Sequencing capital and land market reforms for broadly based growth. Staff Paper Series No. 379. Madison, WI, USA, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin.

Carter, M. & Kalfayan, J. 1989. A general equilibrium exploration of the agrarian question. Staff Paper No. 279 (rev.). Madison, WI, USA, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin.

Carter, M. & Mesbah, D. 1993. Can land market reform mitigate the exclusionary aspects of rapid agro-export growth? World Dev., 21(7).

Carter, M. & Weibe, K. 1990. Access to capital and its impact on agrarian structure and productivity in Kenya. Am. J. Agric. Econ., December: 1146-1150.

Carter, M., Weibe, K. & Blarel, B. 1991. Tenure security for whom? Differential impacts of land policy in Kenya. LTC Research Paper No. 106. Madison, WI, USA, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin.

Carter, M., Luz, K. & Galeano, L. 1992. Land markets and campesino agriculture in Paraguay: changing patterns of land access and ownership in a period of rapid agricultural growth and the prospects for land market reform. Madison, WI, USA, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin. (manuscript)

Childress, M.D. 1994. Capital investments on smallholder coffee farms: an empirical study from Honduras. In E. Lutz, S. Pagiola & C. Reiche, eds. Economic and Institutional Analyses of Soil Conservation Projects in Central America and the Caribbean. World Bank Environment Paper No. 8. Washington, DC, World Bank.

Childress, M.D. 1995. Economic and institutional aspects of land policy in Honduras and El Salvador. Madison, WI, USA, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin. (thesis)

Csaba, C. 1995. Issues note: land reform and farm restructuring. Washington, DC, World Bank. (mimeo)

de Janvry, A. 1981. The agrarian question and reformism in Latin America. Baltimore, MD, USA, The Johns Hopkins University Press.

de Janvry, A. & Sadoulet, E. 1989a. Investment strategies to combat rural poverty: a proposal for Latin America. World Dev., 17(8): 1203-1221.

de Janvry, A. & Sadoulet, E. 1989b. A study in resistance to institutional change: the lost game of Latin American land reform. World Dev., 17(9): 1397-1407.

de Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E. & Davis, B. 1995. NAFTA's impact on Mexico: rural household-level effects. Am. J. Agric. Econ., 77: 1283-1291.

de Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E. & Young, L. 1989. Land and labour in Latin American agriculture from the 1950s to the 1980s. J. Peasant Studies, 16(3): 396-424.

Domer, P. 1992. Latin American land reforms in theory and practice: a retrospective analysis. Madison, WI, USA, University of Wisconsin Press.

Domer, P. & Saliba, B. 1981. Interventions in land markets to benefit the rural poor. Land Tenure Center Research Paper No. 74. Madison, WI, USA, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin.

Eswaran, M. & Kotwal, A. 1986. Access to capital and agrarian production organization. Econ. J., 96: 482-498.

Feder, G. 1985. The relation between farm size and farm productivity: the role of family labor supervision and credit constraints. J. Dev. Econ., 18: 297-313.

Feder, G., Onchan, T. Chalawong, Y. & Hongladarom, C. 1988. Land policies and farm productivity in Thailand. Baltimore, MD, USA, The Johns Hopkins University Press.

Gavian, S. & Fafchamps, M. 1996. Land tenure and allocative efficiency in Niger. Am. J. Agric. Econ., 78: 460-471.

Hanson, R. 1996. Family farm structure and market orientation in the Republic of Macedonia. Madison, WI, USA, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Wisconsin. (thesis)

Kay, C. 1994. Exclusionary and uneven development in rural Latin America. Paper presented at the XVIII International Congress of the Latin American Studies Association.

Kevane, M. 1996. Agrarian structure and agricultural practice: typology and application to western Sudan. Am. J. Agric. Econ., 78: 236-245.

Land Tenure Center. 1996. Final Report: Project for the Analysis of Macedonian Land Tenure and Agricultural Productivity. By J. Melmed-Sanjak, R. Hanson & P. Bloch for USAID, Skopje.

Larson, J. 1995. An economic analysis of land titling in Honduras. Oxford, UK, University of Oxford. (thesis)

Larson, B. & Bromley, D. 1990. Property rights, externalities, and resource degradation: locating the tragedy. J. Dev. Econ., 33: 235-262.

Lehmann, D. 1982. After Lenin and Chayanov: new paths of agrarian capitalism. J. Dev. Econ., 11: 131-161.

Lopez, R. & Romano, C. 1995. Rural poverty in Honduras: asset distribution and liquidity constraints. (manuscript)

Lopez, R. & Whittington, L. 1996. Land market reform and fertility in Honduras. (manuscript)

Melmed-Sanjak, J. 1992. Reformando la estructura: la viabilidad de empresas de la reforma agraria a la luz de los PAE. In H.N. Pino & A. Thorpe, eds. Honduras: el ajuste estructural y la reforma agraria. Tegucigalpa, CEDOH.

Munoz, J. 1993. Rural land markets in Latin America: evidence from four case studies (Bolivia, Chile, Honduras and Paraguay). Washington, DC, World Bank. (mimeo)

Perrings, C. 1989. An optimal path to extinction? Poverty and resource degradation in the open agrarian economy. J. Dev. Econ., 30: 1-24.

Place, F., Roth, M. & Hazell, P. 1994. Land tenure security and agricultural performance in Africa: overview of research methodology. In J. Bruce & S.E. Migot-Adholla, eds. Searching for land tenure security in Africa. Dubuque, IA, USA, Kendall/Hunt Publishing.

PRODEPAH. 1994. Analysis of the viability of a land bank (FONTIER). Report prepared by the Project for the Development of Agricultural Policy in Honduras for USAID.

Reardon, T. & Vosti, S. 1995. Links between rural poverty and the environment in developing countries: asset categories and investment poverty. World Dev., 23(9): 1495-1506.

Salgado, R. 1994. El mercado de tierras en Honduras. Tegucigalpa, CEDOH.

Seligson, M. & Nesman, E. 1989. Land titling in Honduras: an impact study in the Comayagua region. Madison, WI, USA, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin. (manuscript)

Sen, A. 1981. Ingredients of famine analysis: availability and entitlement. Qtly J. Econ., p. 433-464.

Shearer, E., Lastarria-Cornhiel, S. & Mesbah, D. 1991. The reform of rural land markets in Latin America and the Caribbean: research, theory and policy implications. LTC Paper No. 141. Madison, WI, USA, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin.

Stamoulis, K.G. 1996. Perspectives on off-farm income, access to assets and rural development. Rome, FAO. (manuscript)

Stanfield, D. 1985. Projects that title land in Central and South America and the Caribbean: expectations and problems. LTC Paper No. 126. Madison, WI, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin.

Stanfield, D. 1990. Rural land titling and registration in Latin America and the Caribbean: implications for rural development programs. Madison, WI, USA, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin. (manuscript)

Stanfield, D., Zeledon, R., Moquete, S., Coles, A., Fandino, M., Caballero, L. & Stringer, R. 1986. Land titling in Honduras: a midpoint evaluation of the small farmer titling project in Honduras. Madison, WI, USA, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin. (manuscript)

Stonich, S. 1991. Rural families and income from migration: Honduran households in the world economy. J. Latin Am. Studies, 23: 131-161.

Stonich, S. 1992. Struggling with Honduran poverty: the environmental consequences of natural resource-based development and rural transformations. World Dev., 20(3): 385-399.

Thiesenhusen, W. 1991. Implications of the rural land tenure system for the environmental debate: three scenarios. J. Dev. Areas, 26: 1-24.

Thiesenhusen, W. & Melmed-Sanjak, J. 1990. Brazil's agrarian structure: changes from 1970 through 1980. World Dev., 18(3): 393-416.

Wunderlich, G., ed. 1995. Agricultural landownership in transitional economies. University Press of America.