Implications of Economic Policy for Food Security : A Training Manual |
||||
|
||||
Annex 2 : Theoretical Concepts for the Analysis of Economic Policies
Annex 2a : The Salter-Swan-Model 1. Introduction Figure 1: Macro-economic equilibrium
The curve BC represents the production transformation curve. It traces all possible combinations of tradable and non-tradable goods which may be produced in the economy, given the available natural resources, production factors and technology. It is also called the production frontier or production possibility curve, as it is the locus of maximum production combinations at full employment of all production resources. If all productive resources were devoted to the production of non-tradables, the quantity B could be realised, if only tradables were produced, the quantity C could be realised, or any combination of n and t on the curve BC, e.g. the combination A. Any combination below the curve BC means that not all production resources are used (under-employment) and that the economy does not fully realise its productive potential. In the short run the curve is fixed, while in the long run it may contract or expand through changes in the resource endowment or the technology applied. Economic growth can be shown as an expansion (right-upward shift) of the transformation curve. Here it is assumed that the curve is given and fixed. I, I' and I'' represent a sample of (an unlimited number of) indifference curves. One indifference curve shows the consumers' preference between tradables and non-tradables at a constant level of utility. I'' stands for a lower level of satisfaction or welfare than I, while I' signifies a higher level of utility. The typical concave shape of the indifference curves is based on the plausible assumption that the consumers need to substitute a certain amount of tradables with an increasing amount of non-tradables (and vice versa) in order to maintain the same level of utility. To give an example: If somebody had an abundant supply of rice (tradable) but no vegetables (non-tradable), he would be prepared to exchange a substantial amount of rice for a little quantity of vegetables. The more vegetables he has already, the smaller the amount of rice he would be prepared to give in exchange for an additional amount of vegetables. Assuming rational economic behaviour, a household will try to attain the highest possible level of utility with the income (or expenditure budget) available. The budget line is given by the line DE which represents the combinations of tradable and non-tradable goods which can be purchased at a given amount of income (expenditures) and at given prices of t and n. The slope of the DE curve is determined by the price relation (internal terms of trade) Pt/Pn. If all expenditures were devoted to non-tradables, the quantity D could be purchased at the given price, or the quantity E, if all money is spent for tradables. These cases are, however, not feasible under the given conditions, as the maximum quantity of non-tradables which the economy produces is given by the level B, the maximum quantity of tradables is given by the level C (The implications of an excess demand over production are discussed further below). The only point where the given budget line meets the production possibility frontier is A, where the quantity n1 of non-tradables and the quantity t1 of tradables are produced. Point A represents, at the same time, the point where a household (or the economy as a whole as assumed in the model) can realise its maximum level of welfare with a given level of income, by allocating the budget to buy n1 quantities of non-tradables and t1 quantities of tradables. At point A, the marginal costs of production of tradables/non-tradables are proportional to the relative prices (line ED, and the marginal rate of production substitution (tangent to BC curve) is equal to the marginal rate of consumption preferences (tangent to I curve). In summary, point A represents the theoretical optimum as well as the only equilibrium situation, characterised by the following features and conditions:
3. Distortions of the macro-economic equilibrium It is assumed that a rise in government expenditures, incurring a budget deficit being financed by monetary expansion (printing of money), has pushed demand to point F in Figure 2 (or any other point outside the production frontier). We get a situation where demand exceeds production, in our case of both tradables (t2-t1) and non-tradables (n2-n1). In an ex ante view, before the additional money is actually spent and before prices have changed, the new expenditure line is given by GH which runs parallel to the income line DE. Any combination of demand to the right of point A means an excess demand for non-tradables, any combination above A implies an excess demand for tradables and a current account deficit. If prices and the exchange rate were not controlled, domestic prices would rise in both cases: directly due to excess demand in the case of non-tradables, indirectly in the case of tradables through the market-price-exchange rate mechanism (world market prices are assumed to be given and fixed). A balance between production and demand and a new equilibrium will be re-established by inflation: income and demand will increase in nominal terms but remain the same in real terms while the quantity of production remains the same throughout. In our graph (which depicts the real values), the expenditure curve shifts back to its original position (indicated by the straight arrow). If there were a change in the structure of demand for tradables and non-tradables (change of the indifference curves) associated with the expansionary fiscal/monetary policy, the relative prices (internal terms of trade) would change, as the rates of inflation of tradables and non-tradables would be different and induce a relative shift in the production structure towards the commodities with relative price increases. In the case of an excess demand for non-tradables, the budget line would rotate clockwise in point H to line IH (non-tradables get relatively more expensive) with the new equilibrium point at A', where more non-tradables and less tradables are produced than at point A. In the case of an excess demand for tradables, the budget line would rotate counter clockwise in point G to line JG with the new equilibrium point at A'', implying a shift in the production pattern from non-tradables to tradables. Figure 2: Macro-economic changes induced by excess demand
4. Perpetuation of a macro-economic disequilibrium The results will be different if, in combination with an excess demand situation, a fixed exchange rate policy is pursued by the Government. Figure 3 traces such a situation. Figure 3: Perpetuation of a macro-economic disequilibrium
When the exchange rate is fixed, only the prices of non-tradables increase as a result of an increase in demand from A to F, while the domestic prices of tradables are not affected. Due to the price increase of non-tradables, the expenditure line rotates through H to the new position DH. The new point of aggregate demand is F' where n3 non-tradables and t3 tradables are purchased. Due to the change of relative prices in favour of non-tradables, production of non-tradables increases from n1 before to n3 and is in equilibrium with demand for non-tradables. (The tangent of the production possibility curve in point A' has the same slope as the new budget line). As to tradables, demand has increased from t1 to t3, while production has gone down from t1 to t4. In the new situation (F'), demand for tradables exceeds production by t3-t4 with a corresponding foreign trade/current account deficit. F' can only be maintained if the balance of foreign exchange required is made available, for example, by a depletion of the country's foreign exchange reserves, by substantial capital inflows, e.g foreign aid, foreign investments, remittances from emigrants working abroad, or, last but not least, foreign credits. The latter source of financing a trade deficit has been common practice but, as experience shows, has only provided short-term relief and led to no sustainable solution.
5. Main conclusions from the model analysis The Salter-Swan-model provides evidence on the major factors causing structural imbalances and the role of macro-economic policies in either reinforcing or mitigating the dynamic of macro-economic disequilibria. The main conclusion from the model analysis for the design of economic policies design is clear: Reduce policy interventions which impede market processes and encourage market forces to establish a state of macro-economic equilibrium. Even if a disequilibrium emerges which may be induced by external or internal shocks, any policy intervention should be in the direction indicated by market forces (Adam Smith's invisible hand of the market) to find a way towards establishing a new macro-economic equilibrium. This is the basic philosophy behind IMF and World Bank assisted adjustment programmes. However, in spite of the clear and simple conclusions which can be drawn from this analysis, critical reservations need to be raised as to the validity of certain assumptions in the model and to an unthinking mechanistic application of the messages resulting from use of the model in policy formulation: This model presents a purely economistic view. It abstracts, for example, from all supply and demand factors which are not transmitted through the market and are not expressed in market prices. This refers, for example, to all goods and services provided within the household economy as well as all those needs which are not expressed as effective monetary demand. As to the food economy, all sources of food entitlement bypassing the market channels (subsistence production, non-market transfers) as well as food needs of the poor who lack the purchasing power to articulate their needs as effective market demand are ignored. If such factors are overlooked in policy formulation, this implies a neglect of major productive forces and of important aspects of social welfare. It would mean, for example, that a purchase of (effective demand for) weapons counts as a increase in welfare while the food needs of poor with insufficient purchasing power are left out of consideration. The clear distinction between tradable and non-tradable goods on which the model is based with the implied assumptions concerning price levels and price formation processes does not comply with reality. While there are certain sectors whose outputs largely fall under one of these categories (e.g. cash crops for export under tradables, most government and many other services under non-tradables), there is a wide range of goods, including most food commodities, which fall somewhere in between the pure categories. This means, in effect, that the prices of such goods are neither exclusively determined by world market prices (as assumed to apply to tradables) nor exclusively by domestic supply and demand factors (as assumed to apply to non-tradables). Some of the factors which imply diversions from the model assumptions are as follows:
References FAO, A Model for Structural Adjustment - The Salter Swan Model - , Introductory Seminar on Food and Agriculture Policy Analysis (Morogoro - May 1990), Training Paper No. 2, October 1989. Woodward, D., Debt, Adjustment and Poverty in Developing Countries, Vol. II, Save the Children, London 1992. World Bank, Making Adjustment Work for the Poor, A Framework for Policy Reform in Africa, Washington D.C. 1990.
|
||||