Dans les économies rizicoles de l'Asie influencées par le régime des moussons, la petite taille et la fragmentation des exploitations agricoles sont devenues des obstacles au développement rural durable. Ces obstacles se sont révélés importants dès lors que les exploitations se sont intégrées dans une économie à salaires élevés et ont été renforcées par le fait qu'elles ne sont pas passées sous le régime de la propriété privée. Cet article démontre que, sous un régime de propriété privée, les parcelles fragmentées pourraient être consolidées en unités foncières compactes favorisant le leasing ou la production en coopérative, grâce à l'échange de droit de propriété ou d'utilisation. La terre pourrait être aussi passer à un régime de propriété publique en vue d'être exploitée par des «agriculteurs experts». Ces deux changements de régime permettraient d'atteindre des économies d'échelle.
Al entrar en las economías de altos ingresos, la pequeña parcela agrícola fragmentada característica de las economías basadas en el arroz del Asia monsónica se ha convertido en un obstáculo al desarrollo rural sostenible, y el problema no ha podido ser resuelto bajo el sistema de la propiedad privada de la tierra. En este artículo se propone que las parcelas fragmentadas de propiedad privada puedan consolidarse mediante un sistema de intercambio. Se podrán formar unidades compactas de tierras destinadas a la generación de ingresos y a la producción en cooperativas. Las tierras también podrán ser de propiedad pública y ser alquiladas por cultivadores expertos. Con ambas modalidades se podrian lograr economías de escala.
Jian-Ming Zhou1
European University Institute
Now that they have entered the high-wage economy, the small and fragmented agricultural holdings characteristic of the rice-based economies of monsoon Asia are an obstacle to sustainable rural development and the problem has not yet been resolved under the private landownership system. Through the exchange of ownership and location this article proposes that, enabled by private landownership, fragmented plots could be consolidated into compact land units for leasing or cooperative production. Land could also be turned over to public ownership and contracted out to expert farmers. Both solutions would achieve economies of scale.
In general, the Asian monsoon climate brings rains from May to October and a dry period from November to April. Only rice suits this climate, and it has been the major crop for centuries2. Up to the end of the Second World War, a feudal farm landownership had been dominant and most peasants owned little or no land and were either tenants or wage labourers, although there were some peasant land- owners. Farm work had to be done by hand with simple tools. Reclamation of new land had reached its limit. In the rainy half of the year, rice cultivation required highly labour-intensive, sophisticated and coordinated work, resulting in labour shortages. The consequent demand for more labour led to a high population growth rate, low cultivated land per caput and small-sized and fragmented individual (family) farming units3. In contrast, during the dry half of the year, the fewer work opportunities caused serious unemployment, underemployment or disguised unemployment4. Poverty was widespread and persistent. The economies were predominantly agrarian, with the presence of some industry in big cities creating a dual economy5. With natural conditions remaining the same, this economic situation changed after the Second World War, first in Japan and then also in Taiwan Province of China and the Republic of Korea.
The Japanese model of rural development starts in 1946 and consists of nine major components.
Therefore, from 1961 on, farmers' purchase of land was
subsidized by the government. In 1962, the landholding ceiling was relaxed.
However, there were not enough land sales. On the supply side, part-time farming
became dominant, and many able-bodied males commuted to off-farm employment
while their wives and elderly parents farmed. They had no incentive to sell
land: off-farm income was high, distances between towns and villages were short,
transportation was convenient and there was no need to pay high rent for city
dwelling, hence the added benefit of being able to enjoy less pollution and a
rural home for retirement. Moreover, as industrialization proceeded, land prices
soared and sales in the future were therefore destined to be more profitable. On
the demand side, because land prices went well over the income surplus gained
from rice production, it became unprofitable for full-time farmers to enlarge
farm size through land purchase. Thus, much land remained under inefficient use
by part-time farmers. In effect, it is the shortcomings of private landownership
that have hampered land sale.
Hence the resort to land leasing. In 1970, rent
control was removed, and land could be returned to landlords on the termination
of contracts of more than ten years. In 1975 and again in 1980, leases for
shorter periods were legalized. However, although land leases exceeded sales,
progress was very limited. On the supply side, landlords still feared that, once
let, land would be lost (Hayami, 1988). On the demand side, because the small
farm was composed of many fragmented plots located in different parts the
village, the leaseholder could not join them up into large units or change their
shape into roads, canals, ponds, etc. (since the ownership belonged to the
leaser). Therefore, large machinery could not be used. In this way too, it is
the shortcomings of private landownership that have constrained both land
leasing and the efficient use of the leased land.
Since economies of scale could not be achieved, the number of viable farms was reduced. Thus, farmers and cooperatives organized political lobbying for protection and the ruling party was obliged to yield,
fearing a loss of votes (Hayami, 1988). In 1960, a "cost of production and
income compensation scheme" was designed. As the monopsonist buyer, the
government bought rice at a predetermined price and sold it at a lower price,
thereby subsidizing rice farmers, while an accompanying law prohibited rice
imports. Rice prices increased to ten times the level of world prices in the
1980s (Schaede, Lowe and Tokunaga, 1996).
As a result, in this period the
domestic budget deficit for rice rose to more than US$7 000 million,
leading to international protests, especially from the United States. The GATT
Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations in 1993 stipulated a "phase-in"
of rice imports of 10 percent of the total market until 2005. Therefore, when
Japan experienced a disastrous harvest in 1993, rice had to be imported for the
first time in 1994 from Thailand, China, the United States and Australia
(Schaede, Lowe and Tokunaga, 1996). Rice self-sufficiency was over. In 1996,
two-thirds of Japan's food consumption consisted of imported, cheaper food.
Further liberalization is expected (Kristof, 1996). However, under these
circumstances, it is difficult for rice farmers with small and fragmented farms
to survive and for the government to restore rice self-sufficiency. Subsidies
have to continue. A grant of 6 000 billion yen was included in the 1995/96
budget for farmers to adjust to the new regime (Schaede, Lowe and Tokunaga,
1996). The critical issue is therefore how to consolidate and enlarge the small
and fragmented farms.
Small and fragmented farms were efficient in a low-wage
economy since they were conducive to development and diffusion of land-saving
and scale-neutral technology. But in the high-wage economy, they hamper the
achievement of economies of scale. This problem is common to all rapidly
industrializing economies with limited land resources and a reduced working
population in agriculture (Hayami and Yamada, 1991). Of other rice-based
economies under private landownership in monsoon Asia, Taiwan Province of China
and the Republic of Korea have replicated the Japanese model. Indonesia,
Malaysia, Thailand, Bangladesh, India, Pakistan, the Philippines, Sri Lanka,
Bhutan and Nepal may be regarded as at lower stages of the model. Once their
industrialization has led them into the high-wage economy, this small and
fragmented farm structure would also prove to be non-beneficial.
Therefore,
the small and fragmented farms have become the remaining obstacle in the
sustainable agricultural and rural development of monsoon Asia11. This problem
has been taken as an argument against land reform from the feudal landownership
system in other rice-based economies of monsoon Asia, on the grounds that the
Japanese experience demonstrates that the benefits of scale economies will be
lost if estate farming is dissolved (Koppel, 1993; Takahashi, 1993). Although
this problem has been the subject of substantial analysis carried out by many
leading economists in this field for many years, solutions have not yet been
found (Bray, 1986; Francks, 1995; Hayami, 1988; Hayami and Yamada, 1991; Oshima,
1993).
The author's proposals for overcoming this remaining obstacle unsolved by the Japanese model are as follows.
Proposal I
Establishing a
mixed economy of consolidated private farmland and public infrastructure
land.
Consolidated private farmland. Fragmented plots
could be reorganized into large land units through the exchange of location and
ownership. Following is an illustration of such a system (the numbers are
imaginary; the sizes of farms in figures are not proportionate to the grades):
Suppose a village has m (e.g. five) household
farms - Fm: m = 1, 2, ..., 5; each farm has up to n (e.g. ten) plots located in different places - Pn: n =
1, 2, ... , 10.
Also
suppose F1 has six plots, F2 seven plots, ..., F5 ten plots; (see Table 1). Each plot can be assessed on i factors (e.g. five: area,
fertility, access to water, sunshine, convenience for transport) - Qi: i = 1, 2,
..., 5. Each factor can be given a different weight - W: W = [0, 1] (area and
fertility may receive higher weights and, in general, a smaller area of better
land could be exchanged with a larger area of poor land; some plots may be given
zero as weight for a factor, e.g. if a plot on a northern hillside does not
receive any sunshine, it may receive zero for this factor).
Following the
assessment, grades could be given to each farm, e.g. F1 = 10, F2 = 20, F3 = 30,
F4 = 40, F5 = 50. Then, after the main (autumn) harvest, assigning joined larger
land units to each farm according to its grade through exchange, the land
belonging to each farm should be given the most practical shape possible (e.g.
the length of the plot should not be more than three or four times its breadth) (Skovgaard, 1950, p. 44). After this reorganization, each household would privately own one or a few (preferably no more than three) joined, but therefore relatively larger, farmland units (see Tables 2 and 3).
TABLE 1
Before reorganization - fragmented farms
F1P1 |
F4P1 |
F3P1 |
F2P1 |
F5P1 |
F1P2 |
F2P2 |
F5P2 |
F2P3 |
F5P3 |
F2P4 |
F4P2 |
F3P2 |
F4P3 |
F5P4 |
F1P3 |
F3P3 |
F1P4 |
F4P4 |
F5P5 |
F4P5 |
F5P6 |
F2P5 |
F3P4 |
F4P6 |
F3P5 |
F5P7 |
F1P5 |
F2P6 |
F3P6 |
F4P7 |
F5P8 |
F5P9 |
F4P8 |
F3P7 |
F2P7 |
F3P8 |
F5P10 |
F1P6 |
F4P9 |
TABLE 2
After reorganization - two-plot farms
F1P1 |
F3P1 |
F5P1 |
F2P2 |
F4P2 |
F2P1 |
F4P1 |
F1P2 |
F3P2 |
F5P2 |
TABLE 3
After reorganization - one-plot farms
F1 |
F2 |
F3 |
F4 |
F5 |
Some discreteness of plots may be rational. For example, a farmer may need both summer and winter pasture in certain hill areas, or land suitable for seed nurseries or for growing rice, or varieties of soil and situation in certain types of mixed farming. There is also a local custom of working both an upland plot and a plot on riverbanks and islands where work is done in entirely different seasons (Binns, 1950). Many farms in mountain regions consist of three separate estates - in the plains, in the middle levels and on the high levels. The solution may be to lighten the task and the expense of the peasants by regrouping as much as possible the lands which they possess at the various levels, and by reducing to a minimum the capital invested in construction (Government of Switzerland, 1950). Thus the numerous plots of a farm may be consolidated into two or three, rather than one, joined land units. Needless to say, different localities have specific peculiarities which are beyond the scope of this general discussion but should be taken into consideration in decision-making.
Public land for major infrastructure items. Among the large land units, major infrastructure items (main roads, canals, dams, irrigation and drainage network, electricity facilities, ponds, warehouses, other buildings, etc.) could be built as either
Expenses are necessarily incurred in the above
process. For private landholders, some permanent crops, buildings and other
infrastructure in the old plots would have to be removed and compensated and new
buildings and other infrastructure in the new farms be built and subsidized.
Some peasant farmers might be asked to migrate to other areas and be subsidized.
Public infrastructure implies public finance; fees for organizational purposes,
e.g. setting up ad hoc committees, inviting external experts (surveyors,
appraisers, etc.) who are supposed to be fairer than internal personnel. For
land purchase, if consolidation is combined with land reform, i.e. extra fields
belonging to landholders are sold to peasants in consolidate form directly or
indirectly (bought by public authorities then sold to peasants). These expenses
should be borne by the central and local governments, village committees and
landholders in the form of government grants and loans, bank credits and
personal payments. The village committees and landholders should be involved in
decision-making and allocation.
The process of exchange of private plots for
consolidation would not be easy. Individual considerations would constitute
obstinate difficulties to consolidation. The farms resulting from consolidation
could differ considerably in size, type, topography and value. Some farmers will
almost certainly get better bargains than others and probably a still larger
number will fear that others may do so. Satisfactory consolidation may result in
leaving some farmers with poorer-quality land than they had before and it may
not be possible to accommodate all the farmers. This would be compounded by the
inertia of peasant traditions. For example, one family could claim that its
plots are the heritage of its ancestors and could not be given away. Another may
feel unfamiliar with the new plots. There will also be concern about financial
matters. For example some farmers may worry that permanent crops, buildings,
etc., in the old plots would not be sufficiently compensated (Binns,
1950).
Such realities imply that, to fulfil its objectives, consolidation may be voluntary or partly voluntary or may need to be compulsory.
Voluntary consolidation. Combined private action may take the form of the
voluntary cooperation of a group of farmers, either through a formal cooperative
society or through some looser form of ad hoc association. Such spontaneous
efforts should be assisted and encouraged by governments. However, owing to the
above-mentioned individual considerations, complete success is unlikely to
result from purely private enterprise (Binns, 1950).
An example of voluntary
consolidation was the attempt by the freehold farmers (peasant owners)
themselves to consolidate the village fields of Oster Hjermitslev, Denmark, in
1820. Having been unable to agree on a rational consolidation scheme, the
farmers' land remained split up in 12 different places throughout the village.
In 1917, nearly 100 years later, although some amalgamation of the parcels of
land had taken place, the situation remained unchanged, demonstrating the limits
to consolidation by voluntary private action. Denmark's experience is that,
where consolidation has been influenced by the peasant farmers themselves, the
process has not been carried out well (Skovgaard, 1950).
In all voluntary and
partly voluntary schemes, individual interests are a determinant factor. There
is the obvious difficulty of getting a large number of people, however
well-intentioned, to remain in substantial agreement throughout the proceedings. Even a very few recalcitrants may wreck or seriously impair the best of schemes. Thus, government intervention is required. Government action may be divided roughly into action in which compulsion is a reserve to facilitate voluntary efforts (partly voluntary consolidation) and action based primarily on compulsion (compulsory consolidation) (Binns, 1950).
Partly voluntary consolidation. Here, government intervention towards consolidation has aimed at encouraging voluntary action and supporting it by financial and other inducements, legal reserve power and technical assistance. Such activities need to educate public opinion, with very careful and intensive preparation. For carrying out consolidation, agreement can be by a substantial majority or simple majority of those landholders who control more than half of the land concerned. However, owing to the difficulty of securing the consent of a large number of smallholders, even the requirement of the consent of a simple majority has been found to prevent consolidation where it is most needed. This has led some countries to permit the competent authority to order consolidation where a substantial minority of the landholders, or even a single landholder, desire it, if the authority
certifies that the consolidation is in the public interest. The general pattern
is for the consolidation process to be initiated by the government, usually in
response to a local request, and for it to be carried out if a sufficient
proportion of the landholders concerned give their consent (Binns, 1950). Below
are two successful cases of consolidation in Ireland and Switzerland.
Ireland. Before 1870, the ownership of the land in
Ireland was concentrated among a small number of landowners with about half a
million tenant families who enjoyed no security of tenure or protection against
arbitrary increases in their rents and who, on eviction, were not entitled to
compensation for improvements they had made. In the areas suitable for grazing,
smallholdings were consolidated into large pasture and tenants there were forced
to emigrate abroad or to other areas. Rural congestion was caused by
overopulation in the poorer and lighter lands as well as in some other areas of
the country. Hence the "congested area", which refers to any district where a
considerable number of holdings were of such size or quality as not to afford a
reasonable means of livelihood for their occupiers. While the concentration of
ownership was made secure through the system of undivided succession, the
tenants' holdings were excessively subdivided and the number of tenants
progressively increased. As a result, a tenant's farm could have as many as 20
or 30 scattered plots (Government of Ireland, 1950).
During the period
1870-1946, a series of legislative acts were passed to allow the authority (Land
Commission) to purchase (initially voluntarily but later compulsorily) from the
landlords all tenanted land of the country, untenanted land in congested
counties and the untenanted land outside such counties as was required for the
relief of rural congestion. The authority could purchase other untenanted land
by voluntary agreement with the landlords who could also keep demesne (land used
by themselves). Afterwards, rather than selling tenants the ownership of the
fragmented farms already held by them (as in the case of Japan), the authority
consolidated, enlarged, improved and rearranged them by constructing
self-contained land units, including roads, fences, drains, dwellings,
outoffices, peat fuel supplies, etc., then sold them to tenants, former evicted
tenants, former employees, migrants, cottiers and so on. The lords were paid by
a special government stock and the government then charged the peasant
purchasers annuities over a period of 66.5 years (Government of Ireland,
1950).
The rearrangement of holdings was an intricate and tedious process,
for the tenants were often very exacting, and much tact and discretion as well
as technical skill were required by the authority inspectors engaged on this
work. Where possible, the rearranged holdings were brought up to an economic
standard. But even where this was not possible, the rearranged and enlarged
holdings were much more valuable than the old ones and greatly improved the
living conditions of the tenants. The redistribution was partly voluntary
because the authority induced the tenants to agree to the exchange by enlarging
the holdings with additional land (either from migrants' surrendered holdings or
from adjoining untenanted lands), and raising their standard with better housing
and other improvements (Government of Ireland, 1950). It was also partly
compulsory since the authority otherwise could refuse to sell land to
them.
Any substantial economic improvement of conditions in the congested
rural areas depended primarily on the migration of landholders from these areas
to holdings provided for them on untenanted lands elsewhere as well as on the
utilization of migrants' surrendered holdings by the remaining tenants. The
migration was also partly voluntary since the migrants were induced by the
consolidated, enlarged and improved farms in new areas (Government of Ireland,
1950), and partly compulsory, since the authority held the power not to sell
them land in their original areas.
Switzerland. Until the nineteenth century, land reform against feudalism in Switzerland distributed farm ownership to tenants who already tilled the land thus maintaining fragmentation (just as in Japan). Various cantons (prefectures) tried voluntary consolidation schemes but failed. In 1912 the Swiss Civil Code stipulated partly compulsory consolidation: "When improvements to the soil (control of watercourses, drainage schemes, reforestation, roads, consolidation of fragmented forests and of rural lands, etc.) cannot be carried out except by the owners as a body, and when measures necessary to this end have been decided upon by two-thirds of the persons interested who possess more than one-half of the land concerned, the
other owners shall be compelled to adhere to this decision." Appeals could be
made to the consolidation authority (syndicate); then to the administrations of
the commune, district, or canton, or to an arbitration tribunal consisting of
specialists; and then to the central appellate commissions whose decision was
final, so that landowners had sufficient opportunity to defend their interests
but could not block the consolidation process (Government of Switzerland,
1950).
The procedure was based on the principle of compensation in kind, with
due regard to the value of the properties surveyed (in terms of land, permanent
crops, buildings, etc.). Next, private ownership and the location of lands were
exchanged, and this process was supplemented by a road plan that would permit the rational use of the redistributed lands, the construction of outlets for the drainage of surface water, etc. Permanent crops and buildings in the old plots which had to be removed were compensated in cash. As a general rule, communal, cantonal and federal grants represented a total of 60 to 70 percent of the expenses connected with consolidation (Government of Switzerland, 1950).
Compulsory consolidation. The intervention of the central government or local
authorities could also be mandatory, as the Danish example shows.
Until the
1750s, Danish agriculture was dominated by the manorial system, together with a
few freeholders. Manors were owned either by the Crown or, more usually, by
lords. Of this land, about 15 percent was held directly by the manorial owners
as demesne, and the remainder by copyholders for life, who were dependent on the
lords and received military protection. The land was fragmented. Thus, the land
reform of the eighteenth century was aimed at not only giving land ownership to
copyholders but also at consolidating land (Skovgaard, 1950).
The first
government measures in the 1750s relied on the agreement of peasant farmers to
consolidate the manorial fields and did not produce significant results. The
consolidation operations carried out on the Bernstorff Manor were of greater
importance. On this manor, comprising about 200 ha of demesne and about
1 600 ha of copyhold, land was worked by 41 copyhold farmers in three
villages. All the land was mapped, surveyed and classified and was then divided
into blocks of square or rectangular form as far as the configuration of the
land permitted. The blocks were not of equal size, as the principle was that the
copyholders belonging to each village should be on the same economic footing
after consolidation as they were before, and copyholders who received poorer
land were compensated by obtaining larger areas. Thus in one village the area of
the smallest farm as compared with that of the largest farm was in the ratio
1:2; in the two other villages the ratio was 2:3. After consolidation, the
distribution of the farms among the copyholders was made by lot, and the
peasants who had to move from the village to their fields received a subsidy for
new buildings. When the consolidation had been carried out, the lords sold all
the farms to the copyholders, who thus became owner-peasants (Skovgaard,
1950).
The Counts of Bernstorff, as the local authority, carried out the
consolidation scheme from high patriotic and social ideas. The copyholders were
not enthusiastic about the consolidation and indeed the peasants who were to
move their farmsteads fiercely resisted the measure. But in a few years the
arrangement proved to be of value. In 1783 the former copyholders erected an
imposing memorial in token of their gratitude to the Counts of Bernstorff
(Skovgaard, 1950).
These operations thus became the model for much subsequent work in the following years, as a number of lords carried out consolidation activities according to the same principles. The consolidation process was most successful in places where the local authorities ignored the views of the peasants. The government then combined all existing rules of law on consolidation in a new act, the Consolidation Act of 1781, which became the fundamental law for all consolidation in Denmark. It was a comprehensive enactment which prescribed in detail all rules governing consolidation, the technical details being in accordance with the procedure adopted at the Bernstorff manor and with experience gained there. It stipulated that every owner of land in a village was entitled to demand that his or her land be consolidated and combined into a single lot or, where this was not possible, two or at most three lots. This provision applied regardless of whether other owners of land were willing to take part in the consolidation. The authorities, after consultation with all landholders of the village, proposed consolidation of the whole area, despite owners' wishes to to the contrary, in order that the consolidation of land belonging to one particular owner might not interfere with a subsequent complete consolidation. All the holders of land were bound by law to contribute to the aggregate consolidation expenses pro rata, according to the size of their land. A later act of 1792 further
demanded recalcitrants to bear the cost of any delay in the consolidation. As a
result, the land reform, together with consolidation, was essentially complete
before 1835, in which year only about 1 percent of the copyhold land was not yet
consolidated (Skovgaard, 1950).
For Japan and other rice-based economies
under private landownership in monsoon Asia, partly voluntary consolidation may
be the best solution, but compulsory consolidation should not be excluded
whenever and wherever necessary.
After consolidation, there could be two ways to operate the land.
Proposal II
An alternative
reform proposal consists in compulsorily buying rural land at appropriate prices
for public ownership and setting up a dual land system under the management of
villages and regulation by central and local governments. Land for living could
be distributed equally to rural residents for their use for housing and a
certain amount of agricultural production for self-consumption. If a person has
formally migrated to the urban sector, a proportionate amount of land should be
withdrawn from their household. Land for production should be contracted for a
long term to expert farmers who aim at a higher output of rice and other
products so that large land units could be formed and large machinery used.
Contracts could be transferred and renewed according to market principles.
Within the contract period, if the output target is not reached for reasons
other than natural disaster, land quality is destroyed, or production abandoned
etc., the contract could be stopped and sanctions applied. If land improvements
have been carried out, awards could be granted. Production cooperatives or
companies (as presented above but without private land shares) could also be set
up in which expert farmers could work together. Wage labour could also be hired.
Hence a mixed economy of public landownership, individual management and
capitalist wage labour employment. If some production becomes surplus, fields
could be used for other (even non-agricultural) productive purposes. The
above-mentioned shortcomings of individual leases and production cooperatives or
companies could be avoided. Details such as whether the public ownership be at
the state or local government or village level or land prices and the fees and
lengths of land contracts should be determined through a gradual process of
experiments, public debates and expert consultations.
These first two
proposals might be useful for other rice-based economies in monsoon Asia under
private landownership when small and fragmented farms become an obstacle to
sustainable rural development.
Proposal III
In those rice
based-economies in monsoon Asia that have not yet implemented or completed land
reform from the feudal system, reform could be achieved without maintaining the
fragmented plots as Japan did. Peasant farmers could be given one or a few, but
relatively larger, joined land units as in Ireland and Denmark.
Proposal IV
Population
control should be strengthened, otherwise, dividing the parents' farms among
many children for inheritance purposes would refragmentize land units.
Proposal V
Raising
economies of scale in land should be gradual and follow the progress of
diversified cropping, non-crop agriculture and off-farm activities. If, before
the absorption of surplus labour by the development of these sectors, many land
units were already transferred to large-scale farmers using large machinery,
small peasant farmers would find it hard to survive. Thus, land reform providing
limits on landholdings and rent as well as protection of tenants from eviction
would be necessary. As these sectors developed, such controls could gradually be
relaxed.
Binns, B.O. 1950. The consolidation of fragmented agricultural holdings. Washington, DC, FAO.
Bray, F. 1986. The rice economies - technology and development in Asian societies. London, Blackwell.
FAO. 1972. FAO Production Yearbook 1972. Rome, FAO.
FAO. 1993. FAO Production Yearbook 1993. Rome, FAO.
FAO. 1995. Current thinking and activities. Paper prepared by the Sustainable Development Department for the Oversight Panel on Sustainable Development, 22-24 November. Rome, FAO.
Francks, P. 1995. Agricultural adjustment and
the East Asian development model: the
Japanese example. Paper presented at a
seminar at the School of Oriental and African Studies, London.
Government of France. 1950. Consolidation of agricultural holdings in France. In B.O. Binns, ed. The consolidation of fragmented agricultural holdings. Washington, DC, FAO.
Government of Ireland. 1950. Relief of rural congestion in Ireland. In B.O. Binns, ed. The consolidation of fragmented agricultural holdings. Washington, DC, FAO.
Government of Switzerland. 1950. Consolidation of land in Switzerland. In B.O. Binns, ed. The consolidation of fragmented agricultural holdings. Washington, DC, FAO.
Hayami, Y. 1988. Japanese agriculture under siege. New York, St Martin's Press.
Hayami, Y. & Yamada, S. 1991. The agricultural development of Japan - a century's perspective. Tokyo, University of Tokyo Press.
Kojima, R. Dec. 1988. Agricultural organization: new forms, new contradictions. China Qtly.
Koppel, B. 1993. Land policy problems in East Asia: understanding the past and moving toward new choices. In B. Koppel & D.Y. Kim, eds. Land policy problems in East Asia - toward new choices - a comparative study of Japan, Korea and Taiwan. Honolulu, Hawaii, USA, East-West Center and Kyounggi-Do, Republic of Korea, Korea Research Institute for Human Settlements.
Kristof, N.D. 1996. Japanese family farm: a way of life in crisis. International Herald Tribune, 3 January.
Nishimura, K.G. & Sasaki, S. 1993. Agricultural land reform and the Japanese farm land market. In B. Koppel & D.Y. Kim, eds. Land policy problems in East Asia - toward new choices - a comparative study of Japan, Korea and Taiwan. Honolulu, Hawaii, USA, East-West Center and Kyounggi-Do, Republic of Korea, Korea Research Institute for Human Settlements.
Nurkse, R. 1953. Problems of capital formation in underdeveloped countries. London, Blackwell.
Oshima, H.T. 1987. Economic growth in monsoon Asia. Tokyo, University of Tokyo Press.
Oshima, H.T. 1993. Strategic processes in monsoon Asia's economic development. Baltimore, MD, USA, The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Rothacher, A. 1989. Japan's agro-food sector. London, Macmillan.
Schaede, U., Lowe, D. & Tokunaga, Y. 1996. Economy - Japan. The Far East and Australasia 1996. Europa Publications.
Skovgaard, K. 1950. Consolidation of agricultural land in Denmark. In B.O. Binns, ed. The consolidation of fragmented agricultural holdings. Washington, DC, FAO.
Takahashi, A. 1993. The evolution of Japan's land policies in the East Asian context. In B. Koppel & D.Y. Kim, eds. Land policy problems in East Asia - toward new choices - a comparative study of Japan, Korea and Taiwan. Honolulu, Hawaii, USA, East-West Center and Kyounggi-Do, Republic of Korea, Korea Research Institute for Human Settlements.
1 The author sincerely thanks Professors Stuart Holland, Mario Nuti, Christopher Howe and Dr Jim Riddell as well as many others who have given instruction and help.
2 Monsoon Asia contains 19 rice-based economies: China (mainland), Japan, the Democratic Republic of Korea, the Republic of Korea and Taiwan Province of China in East Asia; Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia, Myanmar, the Philippines, Thailand and Viet Nam in Southeast Asia; and Bangladesh, Bhutan, India, Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka in South Asia.
3 "Farm" (or farming unit) as used in this paper means "agricultural holding". It refers to all land that is used wholly or partly for agricultural production and is operated by one person - the holder - alone or with the assistance of others, without regard to title, size or location (FAO, 1972). Fragmentation of an agricultural holding is defined as the state of division of the holding into several discrete plots (Government of France, 1950; Binns, 1950).
4 (i) Those who are willing and able to work but cannot find work are unemployed; and (ii) among those employed, those who are working less than full time and want more hours of work are underemployed (Oshima, 1993); (iii) those of the population engaged in agriculture who could be removed without reducing agricultural output, even though the technical methods in use remain unchanged, are disguisedly unemployed (Nurkse, 1953).
5 Although Japan was developed, its industrialization was based on its import of foods from and export of industrial goods to colonies. Its agriculture was relatively stagnant (Oshima, 1987).
6 Diversified cropping implies a shift from a monoculture or a few crops (mainly grains) to a larger assortment of crops (roots and tubers, pulses, oil crops, vegetables, fruits, berries, tree nuts, etc.). (Oshima, 1993; FAO, 1993). Agriculture - depending on the context - in a broad sense includes cropping (farming), animal husbandry, fishery, forestry and hunting (Oshima, 1993) (the importance of hunting has been declining owing to environmental protection); in a narrow sense, it may refer only to cropping (farming).
7 Off-farm employment of farm families denotes their employment in non-agricultural sectors, i.e. industry and services. Industry contains mining, manufacturing, construction, public utilities, transportation and communication. Services comprise banking, real estate, business, public services that require the highest level of education and retail trade, restaurants, domestic and other personal services that only need minimal education (Oshima, 1993).
8 The first transition is completed when the share of the agricultural labour force in the total labour force (about three-quarters) has fallen, while the share of the industrial labour force has risen, to roughly 1/4-1/3. The second transition is concluded when the service sector overtakes the industrial sector in size of labour force (Oshima, 1987).
9 "Farm size" may refer to the area of land, or number of households, of the farm. The large farm size advocated in this paper for monsoon Asian rice-based economies denotes the large size in land area of farm whose basic operation unit is one household which may receive help from governments, collectives and cooperatives and hire non-family labourers. But experiments on managing a collective/cooperative farm as an agricultural enterprise including a number of households should be carried out.
10 Farms that earn income per farm household member equal to, or above, that of non-farm employees who are living in rural areas are "viable units" (Hayami, 1988).
11 In 1991, FAO/Netherlands Conference on Agriculture and the Environment defined the essential and interdependent goals of Sustainable Agricultural and Rural Development as "Food security, to be obtained by ensuring an appropriate and sustainable balance between self-sufficiency and self-reliance; employment and income generation in rural areas, particularly to eradicate poverty; and natural resource conservation and environmental protection."(FAO, 1995).